Key challenges facing modern finance: making the financial sector serve society
The need to stop the adverse behavior of banks; curbing the desire of economic agents to obtain rent. Taxation in the context of the corrosive effect of tax competition. Role of government in restoring the public’s eroded trust in financial institutions.
Рубрика | Финансы, деньги и налоги |
Вид | статья |
Язык | английский |
Дата добавления | 08.02.2021 |
Размер файла | 37,0 K |
Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже
Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.
Размещено на http://www.allbest.ru/
Key challenges facing modern finance: making the financial sector serve society
J.E. Stiglitz, Columbia University
Abstract
The purpose of this paper is to discuss the broad issue of how to make the financial sector serve society, at Least serve it better than it has until now. Finance has been the centre of attention, for better or for worse, for more than a quarter- century, partly because of its increasing share of GDP, and partly because of the negative behaviour and activities of its professionals. The paper is divided into six parts. The first section concerns the necessity of stopping adverse behaviours (activities). Section II presents some measures aimed at encouraging positive activities and promoting positive behaviour. Section III discusses a crucial issue concerning the urgent need to curb rent-seeking. Section IV discusses taxation in the context of the corrosive effect of tax competition. Section V, using analysis provided, presents measures to enhance the role of government in restoring the public's eroded trust in financial institutions. Finally, Section VI discusses questions about how we can restore trust.
Keywords: regulation; financial crises; boom-busts; Dodd-Frank Act; Great Depression; Great Recession; housing boom; banking; inequality
Аннотация
Ключевые проблемы, стоящие перед современными финансами: как заставить финансовый сектор служить обществу
Д.Ю. Стиглиц, Колумбийский университет
Целью настоящей статьи является обсуждение широкого вопроса о том, как заставить финансовый сектор служить обществу лучше, чем он служил до сих пор. Финансы находятся в центре внимания уже более четверти века отчасти из-за увеличения их доли в ВВП, а отчасти из-за негативного поведения и деятельности финансовых специалистов. Статья состоит из шести частей. Первый раздел касается необходимости прекращения неблагоприятного поведения (деятельности) банков и финансовых институтов. В разделе II представлены некоторые меры, направленные на поощрение их позитивной деятельности и поведения. В разделе III обсуждается важнейший вопрос, касающийся настоятельной необходимости обуздать стремление экономических агентов к получению ренты. В разделе IV рассматривается налогообложение в контексте разрушительного воздействия налоговой конкуренции. В разделе V на основе проведенного анализа представлены меры по повышению роли правительства в восстановлении подорванного доверия населения к финансовым институтам. Наконец, в разделе VI обсуждаются вопросы о том, как мы можем восстановить доверие.
Ключевые слова: регулирование; финансовые кризисы; бум-спад; закон Додда-Франка; Великая депрессия; Великая рецессия; жилищный бум; банковское дело; неравенство
Preliminarycritical remarks
I want to begin by first emphasising that the financial sector is vital for the functioning of any economy. No country has been successful economically without a well-functioning financial sector. On the other hand, a malfunctioning financial sector can lead, as it did in 2008, to an economic crisis. In fact, there were a large number of crises around the world before, but the 2008 crisis was the worst after the end of WWII. It was because of deregulation of the financial market, which began in 1980. And most of these crises we can attribute to misbehaviour or misjudgements of the financial sector.
The experience of the crisis should have led us to change our economic models, our economic priorities, and our regulations of the financial sector. We have identified the problems that gave rise to the financial crisis, but our solutions to those problems have been highly incomplete -- and are yet at risk of being undone The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act whose long title is “An Act to promote the financial stability of the United States by improving accountability and transparency in the financial system, to end `too big to fail', to protect the American taxpayer by ending bailouts, to protect consumers from abusive financial services practices, and for other purposes.” (Effective July 21, 2010). Regarding the Republican-led rollback of some provisions of Dodd-Frank in 2018, this move from increased regulation after a crisis to deregulation during an economic boom has been a recurrent feature in the United States. See, for example, Dagher JC. Regulatory Cycles: Revisiting the Political Economy of Financial Crises. November 27, 2017. See also, for example, “What Does the Partial Rollback of Dodd-Frank Mean for the Largest U. S. Banks?” or “Congress Approves First Big Dodd-Frank Rollback” .
The big question always centres on systemic risk: To what extent does the collapse of an institution imperil the financial system as a whole? America's financial system failed in its two crucial responsibilities: managing risk and allocating capital. Moreover, many of the worst elements of the US financial system, for example toxic mortgages and the practices that led to them, were exported to the rest of the world. It was all done in the name of innovation, and any regulatory initiative was fought off with claims that it would suppress that innovation. However, we do not overlook political forces that shape regulations over time. There is a widespread view that financial innovations are much ahead of regulators.
The financial crisis of 2007-2008 was partly determined by a catastrophic collapse in confidence. Financial markets hinge on trust, and that trust has eroded. Moreover, the crisis in trust extends beyond banks. However, before we treat our economy, we first need to determine what is sick [1, 2].
A malfunctioning financial sector can lead to slow growth because of:
• A failure to provide resources necessary to create new businesses and expand existing businesses and therefore to allocate capital well;
• A failure to develop good instruments for risksharing;
• Predation draining energy from the vitality of the economy;
• Greater inequality;
• Being the major source of rent-seeking in modern society.
A malfunctioning financial sector can lead to erosion of trust in other institutions:
• Especially in response to flawed response;
• It seemed to reflect capture, revolving door between finance and regulators, lobbying, monster campaign contributions. All tarnished the view that there was “good governance” and enhanced the view that the system was rigged.
The 2008 crisis spawned the “Occupy” movement worldwide and gave rise to the Tea Party.
In recent years, the financial sector of advanced countries has failed in all of these dimensions:
• Reduced flow of funds to small- and mediumsized enterprises;
• Excessive flow of funds to socially harmful sectors -- coal, cigarettes;
• Insufficient flow of funds to areas of great social need -- green investments (The Green New Deal).
The long list of “misbehaviours”:
• Predatory lending;
• Market manipulation;
• Insider trading;
• Abusive credit card practices;
• Exploiting market power (e.g. in credit cards);
• Facilitating tax avoidance/evasion and other nefarious activities;
• Front running (including its modern version, High-Frequency Trading).
All these failures have very broad implications. I argue that the American system of capitalism has fallen down and needs government help to get back up. And I think that Friedmanite self-regulation is an oxymoron. I see an essential role for government in regulation and more active lending. And I stress in my latest book, People, Power, and Profits: Progressive Capitalism for an Age of Discontent, that “The view that government is the problem, not the solution, is simply wrong. To the contrary, many if not most of our society's problems, from the excesses of pollution to financial instability and economic inequality, have been created by markets.” The true sources of wealth and increases in standards of living were based on education, advances in science and technology, and the rule of law. Therefore, the assault by free- market fundamentalists on the judiciary, in universities, and in the media undermines the very institutions that have long been the foundation of America's economic well-being, and its democracy [3, 4]. It may not be too late to create a progressive capitalism that will recreate shared prosperity. Too many have made their wealth through the exploitation of others rather than through wealth creation. From this follows the broad agenda:
• Stop adverse activities;
• Encourage positive activities;
• Curb rent-seeking activity;
• Make tax avoidance and tax heavens impossible;
• Rebuild a positive role for government;
• Restore trust in state institutes and democratic values.
I'm going to discuss six areas within this broad agenda of trying to make sure that the financial sector can serve society. And in each of these areas, I'm going to try to illustrate how advances in theoretical work and the analytics, and empirical research, explain these failures and what the government, what society, can do to address those failures.
What I'm going to do is highlight the nature of the pervasive imperfections in the markets and the kinds of potential remedies to these failures.
Stopping adverse behaviours
The U.S. finance, insurance and real estate (FIRE) sector accounted in the middle of 2019 for about 7.4 per cent of GDP. It increased from 2.5 per cent of US GDP after the end of WWII to about 8 per cent before the financial crisis. Moreover, those in the financial sector earned very high incomes. But there was a big mistake made in many countries. They thought that the high incomes meant that the sector was highly productive, that it was promoting the economy's growth and its stability. And that the bankers were being rewarded for their societal contributions in line with standard principles of economics, neoclassical economics. And these are perspectives that dominated the economics profession since Adam Smith.
But researchers provided a different interpretation of what was going on; in fact, the data showed that as the percentage of GDP that went to finance increased, growth was slower. The economy was more unstable. The process of financialisation was more related to the growth of inequality. And it was not just correlation, it was causation. And the causation was actually related not only to the growth of inequality but to the slowing down of the economy [5]. And it is related to a concept that economists referred to as rent-seeking.
Experience showed us then the market participants were engaging in behaviour with excessive risk-taking, which can put the financial system on the brink of collapse. This excessive risk-taking is a “Mother of all Moral Hazards” because, usually, a moral hazard exists when an entity engages in risk-taking behaviour based on a set of expected outcomes in which another entity bears the costs in the event of an unfavourable outcome. However, among the set of expected outcomes can also be the state's promise of bailouts or any other indemnity guarantee. Further, extreme risk-taking behaviour is exacerbated by the expected promise of a bail-out. It creates one-sided bets and lowers the cost of funding (no bankruptcy risk premium) for “too big to fail” banks, distorting the financial sector, exacerbating unhealthy risk-taking and the size of eventual bailouts In 2009 the Financial Stability Board (FSB) started to develop a method to identify systemically important banks to which a set of stricter requirements would apply. SIB is the abbreviation for Systemically Important Bank. The term SIFI is the abbreviation for Systemically Important Financial Institution, which in addition to banks also includes insurance companies and financial market infrastructure providers deemed systemically crucial by regulators. There are separate lists of global systemically important banks, G-SIBs, domestic systemically important banks D-SIBs (known in Europe as “national SIFIs”) and regional systemically important banks R-SIBs..
Such excessive risk-taking can take on many forms, including the excessively rapid expansion of credit (by any institution, of any type of credit), which is a strong predictor of troubles down the line. But to be “too big to fail” is only one side of the story. Many economists were devoting their research to getting around standards and regulations designed to ensure the efficiency of the economy and the safety of the banking system. Unfortunately, they were far too successful. They paid particular attention to the structure of the financial system. Another aspect is the existence, and growing share, of shadow banking systems. Shadow banking primarily represents a risk because of the lack of stability of the source of funding and government oversight.
It is not just the problem of being a “too big to fail” bank but, first of all, of being “too interconnected (too intertwined) to fail” and “too correlated to fail.” Interlinked banks can lead to a systemic crisis (e.g. in the aftermath of the failure of Lehman Brothers). Interlinkages and connectedness are associated with the so-called domino effect, chain reactions caused by something unexpected in one node of the network. Dense networks can absorb small shocks but amplify big shocks, and make it difficult to organise an efficient “bail-in” -- where other banks contribute to preventing bankruptcy cascade.
Greenwald and Stiglitz [3] developed formal models of debt deflation and a theory of monetary policy focusing on the role of credit. In this book, we explain the other factors that affect lending -- among which is the risk, which has only grown worse as the economy's woes have deepened. With Gallegati and other co-authors, we explored the credit interlinkages that have played such an essential role in this crisis. These models explore the possibility of bankruptcy cascades. They explain how global financial integration may serve not only to share risk but also to facilitate contagion, as a failure in one part of the economic system -- in this case, the US -- spreads around the world [6-8].
There are two ways of becoming wealthy. One is to increase the size of the national pie. That is called wealth-creation. And the other is to steal a bigger share of the pie for yourself. And that is called rentseeking or rent-grabbing. And much of the income in the financial sector was associated with this kind of rent-seeking activity, wealth-grabbing -- exploitation of one kind or another.
Research in basic economics and finance has helped to see more clearly what is going on. We have come to understand better what a well-functioning financial market looks like. Ideas like the ModiglianiMiller Theorem [9] Franco Modigliani was awarded the 1985 Nobel Prize in Economics for this and other contributions. Merton Miller was awarded the 1990 Nobel Prize in Economics (along with Harry Markowitz and William F. Sharpe) specifically for “fundamental contributions to the theory of corporate finance”., informationally efficient markets, capital asset pricing, Arrow-Debreu securities -- all these clarify what a perfect market would theoretically look like. And what we know now is that the market that we see is very imperfect. While I was still a graduate student at MIT, I began to suspect that something was wrong with the Modigliani-Miller theorem [10, 11].
In my paper “Modigliani, the Modigliani-Miller Theorem, and Macroeconomics”, presented to a conference, “Franco Modigliani and the Keynesian Legacy,” at The New School from April 14 and 15, 2005, I analysed the Modigliani-Miller theorem in retrospect. I wanted to focus on the indirect contribution that Modigliani exerted on macroeconomics through his pioneering work with Merton Miller on corporate finance.
The most important conclusion of Modigliani and Miller was that corporate financial policy makes no difference to how the firm actually finances its investment. It means that the value of the firm is independent of how it was financed. Therefore, an immediate corollary is that the cost of capital does not depend on how the firm was financed. Besides theoretical aspects, for thousands of people working on Wall Street in corporate finance, Modigliani had shown that they did not know what they were doing.
And much of the research I am going to describe here is an attempt to understand why the market looks so different from a world depicted by the perfect market, perfect information, perfect competition etc.
But to give you just one example of how different the standard theory and the actual practice are, let me refer to some of the discussion that occurred in the years before the 2008 crisis.
A standard view of financial markets that is taught all over the world says that if you diversify your risk, you will become more stable. And unfortunately, many of our policymakers in Washington and at the IMF up until now believe what they were taught in the universities. They believe that a more diversified financial market is more stable. Hence, there were profound implications for how they responded to the crisis as it began to develop.
So, for instance, after the real-estate bubble broke in the United States in 2006, the crisis started to get even worse in 2007 When on April 2007 New Century, an American real estate investment trust specialising in sub-prime mortgages, filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy protection. and then finally it fell apart in 2008 when Ben Bernanke was the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Ben Shalom Bernanke was 23rd Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers (June 21, 2005 -- January 31, 2006), Member of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve (July 31, 2002 -- January 31, 2014), 14th Chair of the Federal Reserve (February 1, 2006 -- January 31, 2014). On February 20, 2004, Bernanke gave a speech in which he postulated that we are in a new era called the Great Moderation, aka the Bernanke Doctrine. It was also the time when the Fed initiated Quantitative Easing, creating $1.3 trillion from November 2008 to June 2010 and using the created money to buy financial assets from banks and the government. In 2005, Bernanke coined his another famous term `saving glut'.. Was he worried about the collapse of the housing market? He said, “No”. He wasn't worried because we had a very highly diversified financial system! He was obviously wrong. We did have a crisis. And because he felt so relaxed, he didn't do what he should have done to prevent the economy from the worst major downturn since the Great Depression that began in 1929.
So, in the last 25-35 years, all the ideas that underlie a perfect market and a perfect financial market have been questioned. Let's take once more as an example the Modigliani-Miller theorem that says that the financial structure of a corporation does not matter. But the question is when and why it does not matter.
To me, it was so amusing that so many business schools taught the Modigliani-Miller theorem and took it seriously because half of New York's Wall Street is concerned with figuring out the optimum financial structure. And none of those people believes that the financial structure doesn't matter. So, we were teaching our students that according to the most important theorem in finance -- the Modigliani-Miller theorem -- financial structure doesn't matter. Yet it was evident that it did matter!
Another example is the research of Robert Shiller He presents results of his last research in Shiller Robert J. Narrative Economics: How Stories Go Viral and Drive Major Economic Events. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; 2019., who also gave a talk here in the same series. He got his Nobel Prize for showing that financial markets are not informationally efficient. Shiller is the co-creator of the widely followed Case-Shiller home price index, which quantifies shifts in U.S. housing prices. In the early 2000s, housing prices in the United States and several other nations rose to levels far above traditional valuations relative to rents. As Shiller's work predicted, this was driven by excessive optimism about future prices: about people getting rich by flipping houses, which contributed to a belief that house prices would always go up. He names these stories narratives, which spread economic uncertainty, discouraging consumer spending and business investment. So, financial markets do not efficiently reflect available information, contrary to the Efficient Markets Hypothesis (the position of Eugene Fama).
Also, I would like to mention my work with Sanford (Sandy) Grossman decades ago, beginning in 1976 and continuing into the 1980s, where we showed that in reality markets could not be informationally efficient [12-15].
If markets were informationally efficient, nobody would have any incentive to gather any information, and so the market would not be informative at all.
So, what I want to try to explain is the need to understand why financial markets differ from the way they are theoretically characterised, and that assumptions of perfect markets, perfect information, the perfect competition, really do make a difference. And I hope it is understandable why the financial sector has not performed the functions it was thought it would perform and why the financial sector hasn't served society.
Besides, a malfunctioning financial sector can lead to slow growth. The reason for this is again easy to understand. The economy always needs to provide the resources necessary for creating new businesses and extending existing businesses. For example, some critical problems are facing small businesses, and lack of funding was at least one of them. The failure to allocate capital wealth will limit growth; the failure to develop instruments for sharing risk will limit growth as well. So, predation and exploitation sap energy from the vitality of the economy.
It is also the case that a malfunctioning financial sector can lead to the creation of inequality. As I mentioned above, it's a major source of rent-seeking. A malfunctioning financial sector not only affects the economy, but it also affects society more generally because it can lead to erosion of trust in other institutions. The way the US government responded to the financial crisis meant that a lot of people developed a lack of trust in government. They said the government had failed to regulate the banks adequately, but then when we had a crisis, the bankers cut off the money and undermined trust in society.
Maybe I should tell a little story of how I was on a small conference call with Barack Obama right after Lehman Brothers filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy protection on September 15, 2008, after the Federal Reserve declined to guarantee its loans and prior to the beginning of the financial crisis. The question was, “President Bush had proposed a 700 billion dollar bailout of the banks.” And I do not know if you know, 700 billion dollars is a lot of money. But the first questions in this conference call were mostly from the bankers. The first question of the bankers was, “Why only 700 billion dollars?” And the political answer was, “Don't worry, if you need more money there'll be some more, but we thought that a trillion dollars sounded too big”. So, it was a political answer, not an economic answer The Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008, often called the “bank bailout of 2008,” was signed into law by President George W. Bush. The act became law as part of Public Law 110-343 on October 3, 2008. The law created the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) to purchase distressed assets from financial institutions with the $700 billion funds to purchase toxic assets from banks. Estimates for the total cost of the bailout to the government are as much as $29 trillion [3]. See Felkerson J. $29,000,000,000,000: A Detailed Look at the Fed's Bailout by Funding Facility and Recipient. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper No. 698; December 2011. .
Unfettered and under-regulated financial markets do not work, and the current regulation and regulatory institutions failed -- partly because one is not likely to get effective regulation when there are regulators who do not believe in regulation.
The response to the crisis seems to reflect the captured government by the financial sector exhibiting a revolving door between finance and the regulators, with the Secretary of Treasury coming from Goldman Sachs or some other large bank over and over again.
It reflected the lobbying, the huge campaign contributions, which all tarnished the view that there was good governance and hence the view that the system was great. It gave rise to the Occupy movement worldwide. And it gave rise to the Tea Party movement and then, in turn, gave rise to the extreme politics that we are now experiencing -- populism and nationalism as well. So, these failures have consequences not just for the economy but for our politics and for our society.
There is also an excessive flow of funds to socially harmful sectors like coal and cigarettes, and a reduced flow of funds to small- and medium-sized enterprises; there is an insufficient flow of funds to areas of greater social need such as green investments; there is a long list of misbehaviours like predatory lending, market manipulation, insider trading, abusive credit card practices, exploiting market power, facilitating tax avoidance, front-running, and its modern form -- high-frequency trading.
And, taken together, what this implies is that there's an important role for government. But of course, if the government is going to perform this role, there have to be good public institutions. That means that if your financial sector is going to work, you have to have a good regulatory sector as well.
The implication is very clear that unfettered and under-regulated financial markets do not work and can be very corrosive to the economy and society, so that means you have to have an effective way of regulating them. Moreover, the current regulation and regulatory institutions have failed -- partly because one is not likely to get effective regulation when there are regulators who do not believe in regulation.
In the aftermath of the 2008 crisis, most of the discussion focused on the excessive risk-taking that contributed to the 2008 crisis and what were some of the reasons behind that excessive risk-taking. One of the things that was pointed out was that when you have banks that are too big to fail there is a one-sided bet: If they undertake risk and it works out, they walk off with a lot of profits, but if things don't work out, well, the government will endeavour to bail them out.
So obviously, if you have a one-sided bet you take a big bet. When things turned out well, the bankers did very well. But when they didn't turn out well, as in 2006-2008, society pays an enormously high price.
In many ways, 2008 was a particular example, where the banks were in one particular area, in mortgages, but if you look around the world at different crises, one of the forms they can take is excessive lending, the excessive rapid expansion of credit.
And the evidence is pretty clear that the rapid expansion of credit by any institution, of any type of credit, is the wrong predictor of trouble down the line.
The issue of “too big to fail” banks now gets a lot of attention, but it's not the only problem. There's also a problem with the shadow banking system, but also of “too interconnected” or “too intertwined to fail” financial systems and “too correlated to fail” financial systems. An example of “too intertwined to fail” is what happened, when Lehman Brothers collapsed. The collapse of one bank leads to the collapse of financial institutions all around the world.
This is an example of what economists refer to as “an externality,” where one bank, one firm, one financial institution does have big consequences for others. The failure of one bank leads other banks to fail and then eventually leads the whole economy to fail.
And there are inherent reasons why it's very difficult to price these externalities, to take these externalities into account, to make the individuals fully respond to these externalities.
I was the chief economist of the World Bank during the East Asia Crisis. In that period in Indonesia and Korea and Thailand, there were systemic bankruptcies, and in a couple of these countries almost 50 per cent of the companies in the country were not able to pay what was owed, and in the others, it was 70 per cent. That meant one had to think about how the bankruptcy of one enterprise or one bank leads to the bankruptcy of others.
And that lead to some research that I did with my colleague Bruce Greenwald and another group of researchers headed by Franklin Allen and Douglas Gale at Wharton Business School at the University of Pennsylvania examining networks of financial institutions and how, if you depended on the structure of the network, they were interlinked among themselves and interlinked with firms, how robust the financial system would be [16-18].
So these studies were done in 2001, 2003 and the early part of the decade well before the financial crisis. We wrote that everybody really has to pay a lot of attention to the nature of the financial structure. Unfortunately, the central banks, with one exception, paid no attention. The only central bank that paid any attention to this research was the Bank of England, and it was only their research department. Andrew G. (Andy) Haldane A. G. Haldane is now the Chief Economist and Executive Director, Monetary Analysis & Statistics at the Bank of England., who was a director of the research department at the Bank of England, understood what was at stake here. Well, the consequences of not paying attention to this were very, very severe.
Many of the macroeconomic models used by the central bankers did not even have banks in them. It was quite remarkable because if you did not have banks, you wouldn't have central banks. So there was a kind of cognitive dissonance: How could you have a model that didn't recognise the importance of banks? But even when they had banks, they used the concept of a representative bank, as if all banks could be aggregated into a single bank [19]. But we argued that that was wrong, that you needed to look at the nature of the financial structure, of how they were linked, whether they were what we call sparse linkages or dense linkages.
And we argued that some of the changes that were going on were helping the system to absorb small shocks. However, if you got a big shock, the whole system would collapse.
I asked people at the New York Federal Reserve whether they knew that when Lehman Brothers went down, or it could have been any other bank, what the consequence for the whole financial system would be. And the answer was, “No.” It was really quite remarkable because during the period from the breaking of the real estate bubble through 2007, beginning of 2008, everybody in New York City knew that there would be a failure of a major bank. We had a debate about which of the banks would fail, but we felt very confident that one of the banks would fail. And we thought it was very important for people at the New York Federal Reserve to know if that happened, what the consequences would be for our entire financial system. Moreover, they never bothered to research it to figure this out.
So the important point is that financial structure does matter and this itself has become an important subject for many researchers. Today, there is a vast literature that has now developed trying to understand what are good, robust financial structures, structures that have financial stability versus those that do not [20-23].
There is a broader question that had to be asked: The banks behaved badly, but why was that? How do we explain their behaviour? And there are two sets of problems. One is the incentives at the institutional level. I mentioned one of those problems, that is, too big to fail, or too intertwined to fail, where the bank did not feel the consequences of undertaking too much risk because the government absorbed the downside risk.
But there was another problem -- the individuals who make the decisions at the bank. The executives, the bankers, they themselves did not bear the full consequences of their decisions. It is a problem that is now referred to as the problem of corporate governance -- the problem of the misalignment of incentives of individuals with those of the organisation and more broadly those of society.
It was a problem that my research in the economics of information helped expose, because what I pointed out was that in the presence of imperfect and asymmetric information, you have to delegate.
If you are the owner of the firm, you cannot make all the decisions. You delegate it to somebody below you, to the managers. But there you have a problem: If you delegate, you have to make sure that their behaviour is in line with your interest. And the basic theory was with imperfect information you could never do that perfectly. And the question was how imperfect was the alignment.
After the crisis, we had hearings in Congress. Alan Greenspan had been the chairman of the Federal Reserve at the time when a lot of the bad lending practices occurred. Alan Greenspan said he was surprised that the bankers had not managed the risk better. But I was surprised that he was surprised. Because, if he had looked for a minute at the incentive structures facing the bankers, he would have expected them to undertake excessive risk.
There are stock options, which meant that when things went up they did very well, and when things went down, they did not pay any price. So, just as the banks got only the upside risk, the bankers got only the upside risk of the bank. It was a doubling of mis-structuring of incentives. They encouraged short-sighted behaviour -- an excessive risk-taking. So, it is not a surprise, given both the institutional incentives and the managerial incentives, that here was excessive risk-taking.
And, as a broader issue that I will come back to a little bit later, is the difficulty of aligning the incentives of the bankers and management more broadly with the interest of society for long-term economic growth. The fact that managerial incentive schemes are excessively short-term in focus means that it is very hard to sustain long-term economic growth.
There were other aspects of adverse behaviour besides the excessive risk-taking that I have just described. The financial sector is often in a position to exploit market power, to exploit asymmetries of information and individual vulnerabilities. Information asymmetries mean that somebody knows something that others do not know. The business of the financial sector is to know, is to gather information, so they often have a lot more information than other people. It is not only according to the principle Know Your Customer (alternatively known as know your client) or simply KYC.
Modern behavioural economics, which has been a subject of two of the recent Nobel prizes Richard Thaler in 2017 and Robert Shiller in 2013., has identified the importance of irrationalities and individual vulnerabilities.
One of the things that concerns me a great deal these days is that AI and big data may enhance these potentials because it means that they can gather a lot more information and use that information to exploit individual vulnerabilities. And that is why there have to be strong regulations to prevent these abuses.
A list of abuses, which I mentioned earlier, include market manipulation, incentive trading, predatory lending. Some of these we were not aware of until after the crisis, like the foreign exchange manipulation that many banks were engaged in.
So it was predictable, and it was actually predicted, that deregulation would lead to a wide range of abuses. What was remarkable was that for 40 years after the Great Depression we had no financial crises. From around 1930 until the 1980s, almost a half-century, we had no major crisis. And the reason, I think, was that we had good regulation.
But then people made the wrong inference. They said, because we have had no financial crisis we do not need regulation. Of course, if you have good regulation you don't see the kinds of excesses that lead you to need regulation, and so they stripped them away.
And it was when we began a deregulation process that we began to see a whole variety of abuses including the financial crisis, but also those kind of abuses that I described before.
Promoting positive behaviour
Much of the discussion in the years after the 2008 crisis focused on how we stop this kind of bad behaviour, like excessive risk-taking. The interesting thing is that there been a lot of good discussion on how we actually get the financial sector to do what it is supposed to do. That is to say, if the financial sector does nothing but exploit people than why have it at all? There is a reason we have a financial sector. As I said, no country has been successful without a well-functioning financial sector, and I described what it is the well-functioning financial sectors are supposed to do. The question is, how we can get the financial sector to actually do what it is supposed to do?
An exciting aspect of the structure of America's financial system is that there is one part of our financial system that actually works well.
The hope was that somehow, by curtailing the profitable anti-social activities, we would encourage them to return to more other traditional activities. We could have done a lot more to encourage positive behaviour. For instance, we could have or should have made providing lending to small businesses a condition for the borrowing of funds or access to the central bank `window'. Instead, even though the IMF and the World Bank put conditions on all the loans and the US Treasury always makes a set of conditions when the IMF and the World Bank make a loan, no conditions were put on the money, that 700 billion dollars that I mentioned, that we gave to the banks.
And what did they use that money for? To pay out dividends and bonuses, but not lend to small businesses. And that was one of the reasons the economic crisis was so severe.
An exciting aspect of the structure of America's financial system is that there is one part of our financial system that actually works well. And that is cooperative banks. We shall call them credit unions. The credit unions did not engage in predatory behaviour because they are owned by the people who put their money in. They are owned and managed by their members, all of whom have accounts at the bank. It is why they never engage in excessive risk-taking, and after the crisis credit unions were the only part of the financial system that continued to lend and increase their lending in fact to small businesses. There are thousands of credit unions in the United States holding assets ranging from over 10 billion dollars to under 1 million dollars. Credit unions may be chartered under state or federal law. Credit unions are not-for-profit organisations to serve their members rather than to maximise corporate profits.
However, there is a broader problem in lending that I want to draw attention to. After the financial crisis Ben Bernanke -- I don't mean to pick on him in particular, but being the Chairman of the Federal Reserve gives you a position of saying quotes that people remember -- he said that the world faced a savings glut. He said the problem was that there were too much savings.
Having been a chief economist of the World Bank, I could not understand that because when I looked around the world, I saw a shortage of savings. We needed money for investment in infrastructure, we needed it for investment in education, and health, and technology -- every area I could see -- we needed more investment funds. So how could he say we had a surplus of savings? It seems absurd.
Well, there really is a problem. Many of society's major problems require long-term investments. Longterm investments are needed to retrofit the economy for climate change, for infrastructure, and much of the world's funds are long-term: the sovereign wealth funds, the pension funds. However, between the long-term savers and long-term investors' needs exist short-term financial markets, with benchmarks and incentives focused on the short term. So, by putting these short-term financial institutions between the long-term savers and long-term investors, you get a kind of paralysis. You have got a savings glut.
And what we need now is to encourage more longterm thinking in the financial markets. And part of this is a need for more public financial institutions. It brings me to the role of development or infrastructure of green banks. Frankly speaking, the attitude of economists, of official institutions actually towards development banks, has changed very dramatically in the last twenty-five years.
It used to be that the World Bank and IMF always criticised development banks (aka development finance institution (DFI) or development finance company (DFC)). It was a curious criticism because they were development banks, but they said they had a monopoly on being a good development bank, and other development banks were not going to be good. Well, now as we look around the world, there are a large number of very successful development banks. And it is not just limited to developing countries. Many developed countries have successful development finance institution (banks). However, let me make a point here: There are problems sometimes because it is not an automatic recipe -- you have to do it well.
The largest development bank is the European Investment Bank, which had several decades of good investment. And now, several new development banks are being founded with a particular focus on climate change. Russia was one of the founders of the New Development Bank, which is called the BRICS Bank, which is flourishing now. During the sixth BRICS Summit in Fortaleza (2014), the leaders signed an agreement establishing the New Development Bank (NDB). The inaugural meeting of the Board of Governors of the NDB was chaired by Russia and held on the eve of the Ufa Summit on 7 July 2015, when the Bank formally came into existence as a legal entity.
Following that, the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB), headquartered in Beijing, was founded and began operations in January 2016. It has now grown to 102 approved members worldwide. It is a multilateral development bank with a mission to improve social and economic outcomes in Asia.
But even my state, New York State, has founded a new development bank focusing on climate change, which has proven to be very successful. NY Green Bank is an agent for greater private-sector investment in sustainable infrastructure with the mission to accelerate clean energy deployment in New York State by working in collaboration with the private sector to transform financing markets.
Summing up, all these new banks can take advantage of new instruments, broader mandates, new governing principles, and play a pivotal role in putting together new projects. This perspective of the positive role that development banks can play in mobilising funds for important social needs really contrasts with what's been happening in the private financial sector.
Now I will talk more about the United States and some of the Western European countries.
Traditionally, many of the textbooks that you probably used talked about banks as “intermediating.” They take funds from households (entities) that have a surplus of funds and give them to those enterprises that need the funds to make investments to create jobs. Namely, that is called intermediation. Well, if you look at the data for the United States, the banks have been dis-intermediating. The flow of funds is going the opposite way. For the last twenty years, money has been going from the firms to the household sector.
So the money that was inside the firm, that could have been used for investment, for creating new jobs, instead has gone to rich individuals who own the firm and that has been one of the reasons why we have had weak aggregate demand and slow economic growth.
Just as an example, we had a tax bill in December 201710. A Trump administration staffed by plutocrats -- most of who gained their wealth from rent-seeking activities rather than from productive entrepreneurship -- have rewarded themselves. It was a big gift to corporations and the ultra-rich. It lowered the taxes on billionaires and corporations. It was a very peculiar tax bill because the problem facing the United States is huge inequality. It raised taxes on the majority of people in the second, third and fourth quintiles, the broad middle class, and lowered taxes on billionaires and rich corporations. If inequality were a problem before, enacting the tax reform will make it much worse [24].
Moreover, the promise was that it was going to lead to more investments. It didn't. A little bit. Most of the money was used to have share buybacks. Share buybacks are just a way of distributing money from the company to shareholders in a manner that is subjected to less taxation. Last year, a trillion dollars went to share buybacks. That is money that could have gone into investment but did not; could have gone into increased wages, but did not.
It has become such a big problem that there are now a number of proposals to regulate or even forbid share buybacks. The United States -- and much of the world -- confronts today four central problems: widening income inequality; growing job insecurity; climate change; and anaemic productivity growth. There is an important positive agenda that the financial sector could be encouraged to do. It has not been doing that; it has been doing a variety of excessive risk-taking, a variety of dis-intermediation instead.
Mark it well: America's large corporations are sitting on a couple of trillion dollars. And the lack of investment is not because profits, either before or after-tax, are too low; after-tax corporate profits as a share of GDP have almost tripled in the last 30 years.
Curbing rent-seeking
I want to elaborate on two other negative aspects of the financial sector: the rent-seeking behaviour 10 The Act to provide for reconciliation pursuant to titles II and of the concurrent resolution on the budget for fiscal year 2018, Pub.L. 115-97, is a congressional revenue act of the United States originally introduced in Congress as the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA), that amended the Internal Revenue Code of 1986. Signed into law by President Donald Trump on December 22, 2017. Four winners of the Nobel Prize in Economics have spoken out against the legislation: Joseph Stiglitz, Paul Krugman, Richard Thaler, and Angus Deaton. that I alluded to at the beginning and the role of the financial sector in tax avoidance.
Curbing rent-seeking is one of the themes of my new book. In this book, I focus attention on trying to explain why the United States' growth has slowed down, why inequality has grown. And a key part of that explanation is the growth of this rent-seeking behaviour. There is increasing empirical evidence supporting that view. The financial sector has excelled in this kind of risk-taking and rent-seeking, and one of the particularly adverse aspects of it is market power.
Banks have significant market power in many arenas, including, most importantly, the means of payments.
Banks have significant market power in many arenas, including, most importantly, the means of payments. Currency is a means of payment, but increasingly we use electronic mechanisms. If you think about it, you know that now most of the purchases are made with debit cards or credit cards or over your smartphone. If you think about how much it costs to move money electronically when you go to the store and want to buy something, how much it costs to transfer money from your bank account to the store's bank account, it costs a fraction of a penny. How much do banks charge a merchant? One, two, three per cent, sometimes even more than that -- four per cent.
So, if you buy something, say, that costs five thousand dollars, you have to pay `transaction costs'. The merchant may have to pay several hundred dollars for something that costs a fraction of a penny. Therefore, the banks in the United States alone make tens of billions of dollars in monopoly profits from this every year. That is an example of market power, which transfers money from ordinary citizens to the banks.
And that increases inequality because transaction costs interfere with the efficiency of the economy; it is a waste of resources. The result is high profits, low innovation, and almost no entry for strangers.
However, there are alternatives; for instance, in Australia, they have actually prohibited the anticompetitive contracts that underlie the maintenance of this monopoly power. In the United States, we regulated the fees for debit cards, but not for credit cards; and even when we regulated the fees for the debit cards, we allowed the Federal Reserve to set those fees, and they set them much too high, and the judge said it, it was much too high, but they went ahead and did it anyway The Durbin Amendment to the 2010 Dodd-Frank financial- reform legislation curbs the excessive fees charged for debit cards only to a very limited extent, and it did nothing about the much bigger problem of excessive fees associated with credit cards..
But the most interesting example is what's going on in India. India realised that the costs of these transactions are essentially zero, so they said, “Why don't we make them zero?” Together the banks created a cooperative framework providing payment mechanisms for free. That should be a basic public function in one way or another.
If you are selling a financial product, you have to put the buyer's interest first.
...Подобные документы
The concept, types and regulation of financial institutions. Their main functions: providing insurance and loans, asset swaps market participants. Activities and basic operations of credit unions, brokerage firms, investment funds and mutual funds.
реферат [14,0 K], добавлен 01.12.2010The General Economic Conditions for the Use of Money. Money and Money Substitutes. The Global Money Markets. US Money Market. Money Management. Cash Management for Finance Managers. The activity of financial institutions in the money market involves.
реферат [20,9 K], добавлен 01.12.2006Тhe balance sheet company's financial condition is divided into 2 kinds: personal and corporate. Each of these species has some characteristics and detail information about the assets, liabilities and provided shareholders' equity of the company.
реферат [409,2 K], добавлен 25.12.2008Economic essence of off-budget funds, the reasons of their occurrence. Pension and insurance funds. National fund of the Republic of Kazakhstan. The analysis of directions and results of activity of off-budget funds. Off-budget funds of local controls.
курсовая работа [29,4 K], добавлен 21.10.2013The economic benefits to the recipient countries by providing capital, foreign exchange. The question of potential causality between foreign debt and domestic savings in the context of the Kyrgyz Republic. The problem of tracking new private businesses.
реферат [26,7 K], добавлен 28.01.2014The Swiss tax system. Individual Income Tax. Income from capital gains. Procedure for taxation of income from capital gains. Distribution of shares in the capital. Tax at the source. The persons crossing the border. Lump-sum taxation. The gift tax.
реферат [14,1 K], добавлен 21.06.2013History of formation and development of FRS. The organizational structure of the U.S Federal Reserve. The implementation of Monetary Policy. The Federal Reserve System in international sphere. Foreign Currency Operations and Resources, the role banks.
реферат [385,4 K], добавлен 01.07.2011Capital Structure Definition. Trade-off theory explanation to determine the capital structure. Common factors having most impact on firm’s capital structure in retail sector. Analysis the influence they have on the listed firm’s debt-equity ratio.
курсовая работа [144,4 K], добавлен 16.07.2016Fisher Separation Theorem. Consumption Vs. Investment. Utility Analysis. Indifference Curves. The satisfaction levels. Indifference Curves and Trade Off between Present and Future Consumptions. Marginal Rate of Substitution. Capital Market Line.
презентация [1,5 M], добавлен 22.06.2015Study credit channel using clustering and test the difference in mean portfolio returns. The calculated debt-to-capital, interest coverage, current ratio, payables turnover ratio. Analysis of stock market behavior. Comparison of portfolios’ performances.
курсовая работа [1,5 M], добавлен 23.10.2016Causes and corresponding types of deflation. Money supply side deflation. Credit deflation, Scarcity of official money. Alternative causes and effects. The Austrian and keynesian school of economics. Historical examples: deflation in Ireland, Japan, USA.
реферат [45,6 K], добавлен 13.12.2010Initial Public Offering (IPO) - первое публичное размещение акций компании, обычно проводимое на биржевых площадках. Публичное размещение акций дает компании много выгод: деньги от продажи, рост капитализации, возможность дешевых заимствований в будущем.
реферат [30,9 K], добавлен 15.12.2008Legal regulation of the activities of foreign commercial banks. Features of the Russian financial market. The role and place of foreign banks in the credit and stock market. Services of foreign banks in the financial market on the example of Raiffeisen.
дипломная работа [2,5 M], добавлен 27.10.2015Features of financial planning in June. Summary and objectives of the financial plan in August. Of the Financial Planning business in Ukraine. Role of financial management of enterprises. Improving financial planning in modern business environment.
курсовая работа [28,4 K], добавлен 11.05.2011The banks history. Origin of the word. The earliest evidence of money-changing activity. A bank as an institution that deals in money and its substitutes and provides other financial services. Types of banking institutions. Loans, checks and savings.
реферат [884,8 K], добавлен 19.04.2011Users and uses of financial information. Range of areas of the accounting and finance. Financial activities and their management. Securities and stock exchanges. Parts of the balance sheet: assets and liabilities. Main external sources of finance.
контрольная работа [20,7 K], добавлен 20.05.2010The global financial and economic crisis. Monetary and financial policy, undertaken UK during a crisis. Combination of aggressive expansionist monetary policy and decretive financial stimulus. Bank repeated capitalization. Support of domestic consumption.
реферат [108,9 K], добавлен 29.06.2011The main objectives promotion as the process. Overview and the Unique Aspects of Financial Services Industry. Financial Services, Customer Trust and Loyalty, Relationship Building. Aims of the DRIP elements as a "communication flow" model of promotion.
курсовая работа [119,9 K], добавлен 25.04.2015The use of computers in education. Improvements in health, education and trade in poor countries. Financial education as a mandatory component of the curriculum. Negative aspects of globalization. The role of globalization in the economic development.
контрольная работа [57,9 K], добавлен 13.05.2014Development banking, increasing the degree of integration of the banking sector of Ukraine in the international financial community, empowerment of modern financial markets, increasing range of banking products. The management mechanism of bank liquidity.
реферат [17,2 K], добавлен 26.05.2013