The peculiarity of the influence of the economic downturn in the company

Characteristics of investments in intangible assets during the economic downturn. Company strategy in the direction investing activities on knowledge: evidence from the sample. The annual rate of growth in staff costs. Application of regression analysis.

Рубрика Иностранные языки и языкознание
Вид курсовая работа
Язык английский
Дата добавления 07.11.2015
Размер файла 404,4 K

Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже

Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.

Размещено на http://www.allbest.ru/

Contents

Introduction

1. Theoretical aspects of investing in intangibles during a recession

2. Firms strategies towards knowledge investments: evidence from the sample

3. Research design and methodology

4. Results

Conclusion

Bibliography

Introduction

Today it is undoubtedly that a company should pay special attention to various types of intangibles when creating its own unique pool of resources. The reason of this lies in the following - intangibles serve as a prerequisite for a long-term competitive advantage for a common firm (Grant, 1996). What is more, researchers and practitioners emphasize importance of intangibles in terms of their influence on firm's performance (Sheehan, 2012; Archibugi et al, 2013). As a result, a growing body of academic literature is devoted to the theme of investments in intangibles.

However, it is noted that intangibles have specific features that trigger contraction of investments in these resources as a first step when a recession starts (Elexova, 2011; Sheehan, 2012). For one thing, outputs of investments in knowledge assets serve as a poor collateral for a loan, as they are mostly subject to high extent of information asymmetry (Knudsen and Lien, 2014). Furthermore, results of such investments are linked with great uncertainty (Hall, 2010). Finally, knowledge investments are widely associated with cash intensity. Necessity to apply huge amount of money in financing of knowledge investments in itself may offset all other opportunities and make a company reduce budgets related to intangibles (Cincera et al, 2012). The relative impact of these qualities of intangibles strengthens in economic turmoil as effect of demand fall and increased credit constraints of a common downturn (Knudsen and Lien, 2014).

Researchers share a common supposition that systemic accumulation of intangible assets at the time of prosperity in an economy contribute to company performance. However, as regards a period of economic turmoil, companies may balance between a bankruptcy and survival preferring to cut investment programs in a crisis (Archibugi et al, 2013; Filippetti and Archibugi, 2011). In the literature effects of different knowledge investment strategies at the time of a crisis upon future performance are not clearly explored.

The aim of the thesis is to determine whether it is more beneficial to contract or accumulate core intangibles resources at the time of economic downturn in terms of the effect on company future performance.

In order to answer the research question the database of 400 European companies is used. Methods of regression analysis helps to determine how investment decisions towards core intangibles in 2008-2009 influence companies performance in 2010-2013.

The study is organized as follows. Firstly, theoretical aspects of the theme are presented. The author observes nature of knowledge investments, as well as a body of evidence from the literature about risks and opportunities of investments in intangibles during a crisis. At the end of this part hypotheses are proposed. The next section aims to analyze companies from the sample, to be more precise - investment behavior of the companies towards intangibles. Research design and empirical results of the hypotheses testing are presented further. Finally, a reader notices concluding remarks of the work.

This thesis may be useful for those who investigate investment strategies of companies towards core intangibles and their relation to economic downturn. For those who are responsible for the process of decision making within a company this study may be interesting as well.

1. Theoretical aspects of investing in intangibles during a recession

Now we would like to examine evidence from the literature about knowledge investments in time of a recession. We might consider that this is an academic field, which corresponds to such large and conventional directions in economic literature as “competitive behavior”, “efficient markets”, “resource-based view”, “investment decisions” and “business cycles”. All these fields have strong theories. But we have evidence that some theories' suppositions might not work in tough economic conditions especially when it comes to investments in intangibles. For example, the last global financial crisis 2008-2009 confirmed that absolute liquidity and efficient financial markets might be no more than a myth. As a result, these flaws make us notice side effects of a recession, which we need to consider especially when deal with knowledge investments.

In the following section we will try to shed light on the features of investments in intangibles, which become crucial when an economic crisis occurs and management makes a decision whether a company should contract, maintain or increase financing to development programs. What is more, we will briefly observe risks and opportunities of different strategies towards knowledge investments in time of a recession. At the end of this section we will try to set up hypotheses about strategies towards knowledge investments in time of a recession.

Knowledge investments or investments in intangibles are widely considered as one of the key company's sources of a long-term competitive advantage. Resources qualities associated with a sustained competitive advantage - value, rareness, inimitability and non-substitutability (Barney, 1991) - are embedded in intangibles (Kristandl and Bontis, 2007).

A business model, which is based only on a combination of physical and financial resources, might be replicated easily, so that temporary advantage of it may be destroyed. Contrary to this, intangibles involvement in a process of value creation gives a company an opportunity to create a sustainable competitive advantage, which hardly ever may be copied.

To conclude, whatever authors refers to a concept of intangibles or intellectual capital or one of its components, very often they reach a conclusion that these company's recourses represent a key factors for a success in a new era (Spender and Grant, 1996; Stewart, 1997; Henry, 2013 - referring to human capital).

One of the classifications implies division of intangibles or intellectual capital of a company into two groups: human and structural capital.

Let us describe each intellectual component briefly.

Human capital comprises all tacit knowledge of a company (Sydler, 2013), that is why it hardly can be codified and possessed by a firm. It consists of employees' talents, knowledge, expertise, skills, creativity, problem-solving capability, loyalty and teamwork capacity.

Structural capital consists of two important subcomponents. On the one hand, it is knowledge created by a company, possessed by it and which may be reported (patents, licenses and trademarks). On the other hand, structural capital implies infrastructure, which a company provides to its human capital: information systems, software, strategic plans, organizational culture and company's procedures (Henry, 2013). Structural capital can facilitate and stimulate innovations within the organization, as it serves channels of communications and influences the speed of knowledge exchange between employees and departments in fast-changing environment.

Theoretical models of a relationship between companies' innovation capabilities and performance should be observed.

Some authors propose models that aim to investigate innovation process at a firm level. These theories study cause-effect relationships in a process of new knowledge generation.

Some researchers examine the interaction between firm productivity and R&D expenditures, denoting R&D as an innovation input and patents (Pakes and Griliches, 1980) or the share of new products in total sales (Crepon et al, 1998) as an innovation output leaving the question of determination of a firm productivity indicator without a strict answer. A. Pakes and Z. Griliches (Pakes and Griliches, 1980) developed one of the first models describing relations between innovation inputs, outputs and indicators of innovation at the firm level (however, the model is extremely useful even nowadays).

Figure 1. Visualization of the model describing the process of knowledge generation within a firm (Crepon et al, 1998)

B. Crepon et al. developed the model of Pakes and Griliches (figure 1). Knowledge capital in their model represents an unobservable increment of economically valuable knowledge which is generated by past research expenditures (Pakes and Griliches, 1980). One of the results of their empirical analysis confirmed that the innovation output expressed as a number of patents or a share of innovative sales could positively correlate with a company productivity (added value per employee) (Crepon et al, 1998).

Sustainable knowledge accumulation at a macro-level depends on external with respect to firms factors, for example existence of appropriate for innovations infrastructure and legislation. These factors may be consolidated in a concept of a national system of innovations (NSI), which is expressed in a stage of development of national institutions and macroeconomic environment. Authors note that strong National system of innovations supports resistance of companies to possible external negative economic conditions (Filippetti and Archibugi, 2010).

Knowledge investments in the master's thesis should be defined.

In this study the author considers two types of knowledge investments (similar to Knudsen and Lien, 2014): research and development investments and investments in human capital. R&D-expenses are defined as generating new knowledge within the organization expenditures (Hall et al, 1986). Intellectual property and intangible assets may be regarded as results or an output of R&D and an innovation process as a whole. As for investments in human resources, they utilize existing knowledge (Knudsen and Lien, 2014) in trainings and raising the level of employees' skills. They imply employee costs, staff development programs and corporate universities financing.

The nature of investments in intangibles and features that distinguish them from investments in fixed or financial assets should be mentioned.

The background assumption of conventional theories implies that all asset types should be equally financed. But it is not the case for knowledge investments and this effect strengthens during an economic crisis (Knudsen and Lien, 2014). The reason for knowledge investments discrimination is rooted in their nature (Knudsen and Lien, 2014). First of all, the output of such investments is highly uncertain - especially for R&D investments (Hall, 2010). Secondly, they represent poor collateral (equally refers to R&D and HR-investments). Finally, knowledge generation is highly linked with information asymmetry, which makes R&D firms finance their projects mainly by equity rather than by debt (Hall, 2010).

What other factors of intangibles investments top-managers usually concern when choosing between continuing and postponing such investment programs?

Frist of all, researchers highlight opportunity costs of knowledge investments and related to them concept - a pit-stop effect of investments in R&D and human resources in time of a crisis (Cincera et al, 2012; Filippetti and Archibugi, 2011; Knudsen and Lien, 2014). To define this effect, such investments have two-component structure: they consist of out-of-pocket-costs (cash) and opportunity costs. Opportunity costs of operational personnel and resources become extremely low when capacities stay without action (in crisis, when demand falls). Consequently, a recession may be favorable time to enhance R&D and human capital development activities. Furthermore, there is a point of view that opportunity costs component is larger for human capital- than for R&D-investments, so that a pit-stop effect is relatively stronger for investments in human capital (Knudsen and Lien, 2014).

However, the next embedded quality of intangibles hinders top-management in their effort to maintain investment programs in a crisis. To be more precise, this quality is defined as cash intensity. R&D expenditures and expenses for employees development have cash-intensive nature that may even offset opportunity cost effect (Cincera et al, 2012). In the literature we can find considerable macro-level evidence that absolute level of R&D investments is pro-cyclical, which confirms that financing effects dominate the pit-stop effect for such kind of investments (Archibugi et al, 2013; Filippetti and Archibugi, 2011). But although in aggregate terms R&D are pro-cyclical, in an economy we might find cases of opposite firm's behavior. Low propensity of a firm to debt capital (or equally - large internal cash reserves) may serve as a prerequisite to the counter-cyclical firm behavior relative to investments in R&D and employees (Lopez-Garcэa et al, 2013).

If we compare cash intensity of human resources development programs with R&D programs, researchers incline towards the less required cash for human capital investments (Knudsen and Lien, 2014).

One additional quality of investments in intangibles, which is significant when we bear in mind tough economic conditions, is long-term nature of such kind of investments. In the literature this feature relates mainly to R&D investments. To describe, R&D have high adjustment costs expressing in unique specialists and new knowledge embedded in teams, which prevent firms to contract R&D-budgets in a crisis and stimulate firms to smooth such kind of investments in tough economic circumstances (Hall, 2010; Knudsen and Lien, 2014). Other researchers confirm such view appealing to phenomenon of technological accumulation and persistency (Filippetti and Archibugi, 2011) and to high adjustment costs for changing R&D in crisis (Cincera et al, 2012).

Previous studies of investments in intangibles during a recession should be observed.

We might note that there are few papers investigating knowledge investments strategies in crisis, especially their impact on performance. However, some researchers examine management strategies for intangibles in crisis and found that increasing expenditures on employees during the economic turmoil when a company suffers from external pressures may sustain the company (Henry, 2013; Holtskoga and Ringenb, 2013 - qualitative researches). Sheehan (2012) found that management development expenditures in multinational corporations headquartered in United Kingdom had a positive link with perceived subsidiary performance during the last economic crisis. Concerning R&D investment programs in crisis authors mostly examine determinants of R&D - pro- and counter-cyclical R&D factors. Archibugi et al (2013) came to a conclusion that company size and economic performance had become less important during the last economic crisis, but a company inclination towards explorative strategies (new markets and new products) had helped to cope better with economic turmoil. Simply increasing R&D budgets in crisis cannot be a strong prerequisite to winning in a competitive environment.

The question of knowledge investments financing at the time of a crisis should be addressed.

It is obvious but meaningful for our examination that all commercial investments should be financed by equity reserves or debt capital. It becomes crucial when the mechanism of external financing is out of operation (crisis, existence of credit crunch). And if there is lack of external money available for borrowing in an economy, some companies (especially those who are cash-poor companies) may cut first of all investments in intangibles (Elexova, 2011; Sheehan, 2012 - concerning training and development budgets).

What makes a company to reduce investments in its competitive advantage in a crisis? Researchers highlight two main effects of recessions on company's operations (which we name side effects of a recession): demand fall and increased credit constraints (Aghion et al, 2012; Cincera et al, 2012; Filippetti and Archibugi, 2011; Knudsen and Lien, 2014; Lopez-Garcэa et al, 2013). Demand fall affects company's cash flows and leaves a part of production capacities unutilized. Increased credit constraints mean low availability of debt capital that may be expressed in rocketing interest rates or rejections of financing from lenders.

Now we would like to show logic explaining how demand drop and increased credit constraints may contribute to reductions in knowledge investments during an economic turmoil. Demand fall cuts down company's revenues leaving fewer opportunities to finance investments internally. This way a company may attract loans, but shortened profits affect company ability to borrow money. What is more, interest rates for debt capital come up in response to increased uncertainty in an economy (credit constraints).

However, to play a trick on financial institutions a company may involve unused borrowing capacity in physical capital (Knudsen and Lien, 2014) to finance intangibles investment. But this play can also become difficult in time of crisis, as unused borrowing capacity in physical capital decreases as well.

Therefore, some researchers introduce a pecking order for intangibles funding in crisis conditions (Knudsen and Lien, 2014):

1) Use internal cash flows;

2) If there is a lack of internal money resources, a firm may involve unused borrowing capacity in physical capital to finance intangibles;

3) If additional borrowing capacities are over, a firm contracts its investment programs in knowledge assets.

Next, risks and opportunities of different investment strategies over a crisis towards intangibles are eamined.

We need to mention that a company may consider not only objective characteristics of intangibles investments, such as shortage of internal cash flows, pit-stop effects or cash intensity of investments, but also subjective thoughts about future consequences of management decisions (risks and opportunities of different strategies). Board of directors and top-management of companies usually have strategies that relate to human resources development and R&D-activities (Edler et al, 2002; Sheehan, 2012), where future prospects are examined.

It is a widespread belief in the literature that cuts of intangibles during a crisis have a strongly negative influence on a company competitive advantage (Cincera et al, 2012; Elexova, 2011; Sheehan, 2012). Consequently, if a company reduces its intangibles investment programs, it may face increased risks of falling behind those companies who continue investing in knowledge assets during economic turmoil. However, contracting investments may allow the company to wait out a storm in an economy and stay alive. Concerning an opposite option - if a company hold or increase its knowledge investments in crisis, it may hope to gain competitive advantage later on in an expected upswing (Cincera et al, 2012). Nevertheless, applying this strategy may significantly increase the risk to suffer from illiquidity problem.

Summarizing previous experience, we might build a table with risks and opportunities of different intangibles investments strategies.

Table 1 Characteristics of two opposite knowledge investments strategies

Strategy/Risks or opportunities

Risks

Opportunities

Reduce knowledge investments

To lose competitive advantages

To survive and save a firm in order to grow in future

Hold or increase knowledge investments

To go bankrupt because of illiquidity problem

To become a leader if majority of competitors reduce investments in intangibles

We would like to note that in academic literature there is no strict answer about optimal strategy towards R&D and investments in employees in time of a crisis. Believing in a fact that accumulation of intangibles should be carried out whenever possible scholars tend to find and examine factors that put obstacles in the way of maintaining or increasing of knowledge investments. But we found evidence that although knowledge investments are widely considered to contribute to a competitive advantage and even to a leadership position of a company, in time of exogenous shocks accumulation of intangibles is not a clear action plan for a company. In addition, there is a lack of empirical justification of a strong relationship between company investment decisions towards intangibles during an economic downturn and future organizational performance.

Time boundaries for the last global financial crisis should be stated.

The author considers 2008 and 2009 years as a recession. In comparable studies recession years are defined in exactly the same way (for example, Archibugi et al, 2013) In addition, some statistics is introduced. Real GDP growth rates of United Kingdom, Germany and France reached the bottom line in 2008-2009 for the period of 2005-2014. Only in 2012 and 2013 Germany demonstrated worse results if we compare them with the corresponding growth rates in 2008.

European stock markets reacted immediately in 2008 to negative economic news. The major European stock indices (FTSE 100 - United Kingdom, DAX - Germany and Euronext 100 - France, Netherlands and some other countries) dropped in 2008 by more than 20% on average.

Hypotheses justification and formulation

In the final part of this chapter hypotheses about knowledge investments strategies in crisis are suggested. The process of hypotheses formulation has certain structure and implies several steps.

Firstly, remarkable qualities of intangibles are listed. They are competitive advantage, information asymmetry, poor collateral, high uncertainty, opportunity costs, cash intensity, long-term nature. After that, the strength of a relationship between these qualities and investments in intangibles is defined (whether they equally relate to both kinds of intangibles or this is a quality more typical for a certain kind of intangibles). Next, we specify whether a quality has a positive or negative contribution to accumulation of intangibles in time of a recession. Finally, we assign weights to all qualities distinguishing between a weight for R&D expenditures and a weight for expenses on employees. If a quality equally relates to R&D and expenses on employees, both weights equal +0.5 or -0.5. If the quality more relates to one kind of intangibles, the weight for this kind of intangibles equals 1 or -1 and the weight for another kind of intangibles equals 0.5 or -0.5 correspondingly. Concerning a sign of a weight (positive or negative), it depends on the direction of contribution, which a quality makes towards accumulation of intangibles (mentioned above).

For hypotheses suggestion it is important to calculate sums of weights values for R&D and expenses on employees. Positive sign of the sum means that for this particular kind of investments within our system of suppositions opportunities outweigh risks and it is more beneficial for a company to accumulate this kind of intangibles in crisis. For a negative sign of the sum the reasoning is opposite.

Table 2 Net effect calculation for risks and opportunities of knowledge investments in crisis

Feature of intangibles

Strength of relationships between a quality and two types of knowledge investments

How does a quality affect knowledge investments in crisis

Weight of a quality for R&D expenditures

Weight of a quality for expenses on employees

1

Competitive advantage

Equally relates to R&D and expenses on employees

Positively

+0.5

+0.5

2

Information asymmetry, poor collateral

Equally relates to R&D and expenses on employees

Negatively

-0.5

-0.5

3

High uncertainty

More relates to R&D

Negatively

-1

-0.5

4

Opportunity costs

More relates to expenses on employees

Positively

+0.5

+1

5

Cash intensity

More relates to R&D

Negatively

-1

-0.5

6

Long-term nature

More relates to R&D

Positively

+1

+0.5

Sum

-0.5

+0.5

To conclude, the analysis of embedded features of knowledge investments allows us to suggest the following hypotheses:

H1: Maintaining or increasing R&D budgets during a recession depresses performance of an organization in a period of future economic recovery,

H2: Increasing financing of human resources development programs in time of an economic downturn favors company performance in a period of future economic recovery.

2. Firms strategies towards knowledge investments: evidence from the sample

Now we would like to describe the sample, which we use in our analysis. The database, which serves as a basement for our sample, was collected by participants of the research group “Empirical corporate finance” (National Research University - Higher School of Economics Perm branch) during the period 2012-2014 This study comprises research findings from the «The Changing Role of Companies' Intangibles over the Crisis» carried out within The National Research University Higher School of Economics' Academic Fund Program in 2013, grant No 13-05-0021.

The parent sample represents the panel data and includes European public companies from Amadeus source of Bureau van Dijk business information service. It covers 1694 European companies from Great Britain, Germany, France, Italy and Spain for the period from 2004 to 2013. A part of this database that includes general information of the companies (country of origin, a company age and industry) as well as data from financial reports was taken from Amadeus source. Some data such as historical values of companies' market capitalization and research and development budgets was found in Bloomberg Professional service (the Terminal). Finally, some specific information that relates to intangible capital of a company was picked up in public sources of information (companies' web-sites and news agencies reports).

In order to answer the research question, the whole database of the European companies was restricted to 378 companies. The key factor for companies to fit the restricted sample was official disclosure of intangible investments (R&D and HR expenses) in annual reports in 2008 and 2009 - the period of economic turmoil. We need to mention that Italian and Spanish companies were excluded from our consideration. In the following part of this section the restricted sample of the companies will be characterized from different angles.

Geographical distribution of the companies is presented below. The majority of the sample companies are headquartered in United Kingdom and Germany (42% and 39% respectively). Slightly fewer companies have French origin (19%).

Table 3 Numerical distribution of the sample by country

Country

Number of companies

Share

1

United Kingdom

160

42%

2

Germany

145

39%

3

France

73

19%

Total

378

100%

It is remarkable that the age of companies from the sample averages 55 years. We might conclude that companies from the sample are mature enough. The median age of the companies is fewer - about 32. This finding does not disappear when we go deeper into the database - up to a country level: in United Kingdom, Germany and France the median age represents less values than the average age.

Table 4 Age of companies from the sample, in years

Subsample

Average age of companies

Median age

Min.age

Max.age

1

United Kingdom

43

28

10

129

2

Germany

64

32

9

196

3

France

56

45

11

177

4

All countries

55

32

9

196

Very interesting that the oldest company from the sample is headquartered in Germany. Its name is Koenig & Bauer AG (letter C, NACE classification, manufacturing industry) and it has operated from 1817 (in 2013 its age was 196 years).

Also we need to mention that our sample does not contain newly-established firms for the period from 2004 to 2013. The youngest firm from the sample was found in 2004 (in 2013 it was 9 years old).

Table 5 contains information about the sample companies size. As to this question, we consider book value of assets and a number of employees as indicators of a company size. Referring to particular values we have evidence that average company in our sample is rather big than small. Although distribution in cases of both indicators is biased towards companies, which size is smaller than a median value, minimum value of company's assets is about €2m, and maximum is about €324bn.

Table 5 Characteristics of the size of companies from the sample, 2013

Indicator

Mean

Median

Std.dev.

Min

Max

N.obs.

1

Book value of assets, € mln

10 826

435

33 163

2

324 333

312

2

Number of employees

22 907

2 136

55 814

13

546 811

312

Any company from the sample employs at least 13 people. It means that the sample does not contain micro enterprises with personnel less than ten people [3, European Commission classification]. The company from the sample with the highest number of employees is Volkswagen AG (letter C, NACE classification, manufacturing industry). In 2013 it employed more than 546 thousand people.

We would like to note that values in Table 5 refer to the last year of the sample that is 2013. In Appendix A a reader may find the extended table with a country-level data about the sample companies' size.

In the analysis the authors consider the country specifics relating to innovation opportunities and efficiency of labor markets. As to this question they refer to the dataset of the Global Competitiveness report, which is published by the World Economic Forum on the yearly basis [12]. Labor market efficiency indicator from the report rises if the labor market works more effectively and is more flexible (employees hold down appropriate jobs and can shift to another economic activity rapidly and with low cost [22]). Innovation indicator regards the role of private and public sectors in research and development activities of an economy, the presence of research institutions as well as the extent of their collaboration with industries [22].

Presented diagram illustrates that the labor market in United Kingdom stayed more efficient than labor markets in Germany and France for the observed period of 2010-2013. The above diagram notes that innovation index in Germany was higher than the index in United Kingdom and France if concerning the period 2010-2013 (however the difference is not substantial).

The question of sample representativeness is crucial enough. The answer to this question reveal to what extent we might diffuse results of our analysis. In further paragraphs we will try to consider this issue by emphasizing the points of:

1. Relation between gross domestic product of the three countries and the whole product of European Union;

2. Sample companies coverage of economic activities by NACE classification;

3. A share of large firms and a group of small and medium-sized enterprises (SME) in national economies in comparison with data from population (Eurostat source of information [2]).

First of all, without a shadow of doubt the countries under consideration make a major contribution to European gross domestic product (table 6). Germany, United Kingdom and France represent the driving force of European economy comprising together more than a half of European Union GDP (about 52 per cent).

Table 6 Gross domestic product of countries under consideration, 2014 [11]

Region, country

GDP at market prices, trillion euro

European Union (28 countries)

13,9

Germany

2,9

United Kingdom

2,2

France

2,1

Germany, UK and France

7,3

Share of Germany, UK and France in European Union GDP

52%

Concerning economic activities of the companies under consideration the database covers almost all economic groups presented in the European Commission classification (NACE, Rev. 2 (2008)). In Appendix B the extended table with all economic groups and corresponding distribution of the sample companies is presented.

NACE, Rev. 2 (2008) implies division of all possible economic activities by 21 groups, from A to U letters [26]. Seventeen groups out of these twenty-one have at least one firm as a representative in the sample, which constitutes about 81 percent coverage of all economic activities by the sample.

Almost one third of the sample companies (120 firms, 32%) are engaged in professional, scientific and technical activities (M group of NACE, Rev.2). Slightly fewer companies (110 firms, 29%) operate in a manufacturing sector of an economy. About one tenth of the sample (44 firms, 12%) is linked with information and communication technologies. Nine and four per cent of the sample relate to financial and insurance activities and wholesale and retail trade correspondingly (figure 7).

At the end of examination of the sample representativeness we would like to analyze companies distribution by a size class and compare it with corresponding population statistics.

For the purposes of our analysis we will divide all companies by two groups depending on a size class: (1) small and medium-sized enterprises (SME) and (2) large companies. Widespread classification implies further division of SME by micro, small and medium-sized companies [24]. But such kind of deepening will needlessly complicate examination, so that we will specify only two large groups.

By definition of European Commission SME companies should have less than 250 employees and either sales not more than €50m or book value of assets not more than €43m [24]. Large companies, consequently, should have a higher number of employed staff and bigger financial indicators. We note that in our analysis we follow denoted recommendations.

A large share of SME characterizes European economy. Relying on Eurostat information about 99.8 per cent of all companies in European Union may be regarded as SME (table 7). As for a country-level - share of SME in the whole economy is almost the same in United Kingdom and France. And only in Germany there is a slightly smaller share of SME - 99.5 per cent.

We would also like to note some remarkable values from Eurostat, which relate to statistics about population. Significant share of all European companies operate in countries presented in the sample (United Kingdom, Germany and France) - almost one third, about 29 per cent. SME from the three countries comprise the same 29 per cent in all European amount of SME. Concerning large companies - almost a half of such kind of European firms (48 per cent) are headquartered either in Germany, or in United Kingdom, or in France.

The sample distribution by size class considerably differs from corresponding population distribution (table 7). Actually about 80 per cent of all sample companies are large. For example, more than 90 per cent of German firms from the sample may be classified as big. Slightly less share of companies from France may be concerned as big firms (89 per cent). And only English firms for one third consists of SME. But it is anyway far below the level of SME share in the population (table 7).

The reason why the sample contains mainly large companies in contrary to SME is that it consists of public enterprises. It is obvious that public companies are rather big if we compare them with private ones. Therefore, we need to bear in mind that the average size of companies from our sample is big enough because of their nature (public enterprises).

In conclusion, we might say that results of our analysis may extend to large European companies (not SME). Justification for this statement may be as follows: geographically the sample covers a part of Europe where about a half of European GDP is produced and a half of European large enterprises operate.

Table 7 Consolidated statistics about SME presence in the sample and comparison with population

Population (in thousand units) [2], 2012

The sample (in units), 2012

Country, region

All

SME

SME/ All

Large firms (LF)

LF/ All

All

SME

SME/ All

Large firms (LF)

LF/ All

European Union (28 countries)

22 098 The value was available only for 2011.

22 0551

99,8%

441

0,2%

378

76

20,1%

302

79,9%

United Kingdom

1 704

1 698

99,7%

6

0,3%

160

56

35,0%

104

65,0%

Germany

2 190

2 179

99,5%

11

0,5%

145

12

8,3%

133

91,7%

France

2 5671

2 5631

99,8%

41

0,2%

73

8

11,0%

65

89,0%

Gross for Germany, UK and France

6 461

6 440

21

Share of German, English and French firms in all European Union firms

29%

29%

48%

In the following part of the analysis we will describe dynamics of performance indicators and amount of knowledge investments for companies from the sample from 2004 to 2013.

Figure 8 demonstrates historical mean and median values of one of the performance indicators - Economic Value Added divided by book value of company's assets. We might note that 2008-2009 refers to a bottom line for this indicator for the observed period. Time before the world recession and after it: 2005-2007 and 2010-2011 periods - on the contrary are characterized with the highest levels of the relative indicator of company economic performance. The latest part of the observed period, 2012-2013, shows ambiguous dynamics of EVA/Assets, but the values anyway stay higher than ones from the bottom line of 2008-2009.

Figure 8. Dynamics of EVA/Assets of the sample companies

Another indicator of company economic performance is the return on assets (ROA, EBIT divided by book value of company's assets). Its historical dynamics is similar to one of EVA/Assets, especially when we observe the bottom line of indicators in 2009. However, ROA dynamics have some distinctive features:

(1) Median values of ROA after 2009 do not return to levels of ROA before crisis and even in 2012 and 2013 fall below the 2008 level of ROA;

(2) The mean value of ROA in 2011 goes down and reminds the dynamics of the mean value of EVA/Assets the same year. However ROA's plummeting is deeper, because in 2011 it becomes lower than it was in 2008, though 2011 is considered as a period of recovery, not a crisis.

Figure 9. Dynamics of ROA of the sample companies

Figure 10 demonstrates historical dynamics of mean and median values of R&D expenditures of companies from the sample. We need to note that the expenditures were calculated as real values of 2008 prices. The historical dynamics of R&D for the observed period looks like a hollow with a decrease from 2004 to 2005 (2006 for mean values), relatively stable values till 2009 (a bottom line for R&D) and a raise from 2009 till 2013. Particular values of R&D expenditures may be found in Appendix C, table 3.

Figure 10. Dynamics of R&D for the sample companies

Figure 11 shows historical dynamics of mean and median values of expenses on employees. All numbers are calculated as real values in 2008 prices. The mean values demonstrate positive dynamics almost in all observed years. The most remarkable growth was in 2011 and 2012. However, in 2007 the mean value of investments in human resources reported a decrease comparing with 2006 value.

Median values of expenses on employees declined in 2005 and in 2008-2009. Before and right after 2008-2009 recession the median values demonstrated steady growth.

Figure 11. Dynamics of expenses on employees for the sample companies

In the following part of the analysis we will describe growth rates of knowledge investments of the companies from the sample. What is more, we will observe different strategies of the companies related to knowledge capital contraction or accumulation in three successive periods: before, during and right after world crisis 2008-2009. investment asset strategy cost

Table 8 demonstrates annual growth rates of investments on R&D and numbers of positive and negative growth rates during the crisis. In 2008 the number of companies that accumulated R&D (increased R&D investments in 2008) equal the number of companies that contracted R&D expenses. In 2009 there was more decisions to reduce R&D budgets than to enhance (221 to reduce in comparison with 147 to increase). For information purposes we add information about growth rates for the first year of economic recovery. And numbers of contraction and accumulation of R&D budgets in 2010 was opposite to corresponding numbers of 2009: in 2010 243 companies increased R&D in comparison with 120 firms that reduce R&D the same year (see table 8).

Table 8 Descriptive statistics of annual R&D growth rates (sample companies)

Period

Mean

Median

St.dev.

Min

Max

N.obs

N.of increase

N.of decrease

1

2007-2008

4%

0%

50%

-99%

473%

366

183

183

2

2008-2009

16%

-4%

211%

-100%

3496%

368

147

221

3

2009-2010 For information purposes

13%

7%

58%

-100%

795%

363

243

120

Annual growth rates of expenses on employees in the period of recession produce ambiguous evidence. In the first year of recession there was more companies that contract expenses on staff. However, in the second year of crisis and the first year of recovery (2009 and 2010) companies that enhance budgets related to human resources development prevailed (see table 9).

Table 9 Descriptive statistics of annual growth rates of expenses on employees (sample companies)

Period

Mean

Median

St.dev.

Min

Max

N.obs

N.of increase

N.of decrease

1

2007-2008

0%

-1%

27%

-76%

257%

366

172

194

2

2008-2009

2%

1%

34%

-82%

564%

368

191

177

3

2009-20101

7%

5%

24%

-100%

225%

372

264

108

The following two tables compare geometric average annual growth rates of R&D and HR budgets for three periods defined as (1) before (2004-2007), (2) during (2007-2009) and (3) right after (2009-2013) world crisis.

Average annual Growth rates and general direction of decisions about contraction or accumulation for both R&D investments and expenses on employees may be defined as similar. Average annual growth rates for both R&D and expenses on staff during the crisis are not positive, though during the periods before and after recession they are all above zero (see tables 10 and 11).

Table 10 Descriptive statistics of geometric average annual R&D growth rates (sample companies) for the three periods

Period

Mean

Median

St.dev.

Min

Max

N.obs

N.of increase

N.of decrease

1

2004-2007

21%

6%

112%

-67%

1473%

382

241

141

2

2007-2009

-2%

-3%

32%

-100%

394%

383

159

224

3

2009-2013

4%

5%

20%

-100%

58%

252

173

79

General direction of decisions to enhance or reduce the investments in 2004-2013 followed some pattern: in a crisis period decisions to contract knowledge investments prevail, but during the periods of prosperity and recovery companies prefer in average increasing such kind of investments (see tables 10 and 11).

Table 11 Descriptive statistics of geometric average annual growth rates of expenses on employees (sample companies) for the three periods

Period

Mean

Median

St.dev.

Min

Max

N.obs

N.of increase

N.of decrease

1

2004-2007

11%

4%

59%

-46%

1071%

378

265

113

2

2007-2009

0%

-1%

18%

-49%

163%

378

181

197

3

2009-2013

3%

3%

16%

-80%

196%

327

233

94

The following section aims to describe how the sample companies deal with R&D and investments in human resources during the observed period 2004-2013. We again divided time horizon into three relative groups: before, during and after the world crisis. After that we examined geometric average annual growth rates of the investments in each time period. If a growth rate is positive, we assume that a company accumulate corresponding investments during the period, and vice versa. Results of such kind of analysis are summarized in the following diagrams and tables. In addition, corresponding statistics in numbers is presented in Appendix D and E.

Figure 12 shows that about two thirds of the sample companies (63%) in average increased R&D in 2004-2007. However, during the crisis the situation changed - the companies tended to contract R&D budgets and independently of the decision about R&D investments in previous time period (in two groups the share of companies that reduced R&D in 2008-2009 equals 59%).

Figure 12. Percentage distribution of sample companies among contraction or accumulation strategies relating R&D, sequence of the three periods

Concerning possible strategies relating R&D during three periods we might conclude that the most widespread behavior during the observed period was to contract R&D in crisis and enhance R&D budgets in time of prosperity and recovery (almost one third of the companies, 27%). The share of companies that continued to increase R&D during all observed periods was about 17%. Companies that in average reduced R&D from 2004 to 2013 form a group of 4%.

Table 12 Distribution of the sample companies among accumulation (^) or contraction (v) strategies relating R&D, three periods

R&D expenditures

N.

2004-2007

2007-2009

2009-2013

Share of companies

1

^

^

^

17%

2

^

^

v

9%

3

^

v

^

27%

4

^

v

v

10%

5

v

^

^

8%

6

v

^

v

7%

7

v

v

^

17%

8

v

v

v

4%

Total

100%

Figure 13 shows how companies dealt in average with R&D in 2009-2013 depending on the strategy in previous years (crisis). It is interesting enough that in the group of companies that in average reduced R&D in 2007-2009 the share of companies that in average enhanced R&D in 2009-2013 is bigger than in the group of companies that in average increased R&D in 2007-2009 (76% against 62%).

Figure 13. Percentage distribution of sample companies among contraction or accumulation strategies relating R&D, sequence of two periods

Almost a half (45%) of all sample companies in average decreased R&D in crisis and improved R&D budgets during the following recovery. About a quarter of all companies (26%) in average continued to increase the investments both in crisis and in recovery period (see table 13 for details).

Table 13 Distribution of the sample companies among accumulation (^) or contraction (v) strategies relating R&D, two periods

R&D expenditures

N.

2007-2009

2009-2013

Share of companies

1

^

^

26%

2

^

v

16%

3

v

^

45%

4

v

v

14%

Total

100%

Figure 14 demonstrates how companies dealt with investments in employees (increased or reduced) depending on the behavior in a previous period. We would like to note that the companies, which raised the budgets in 2004-2007, tended to continue increasing expenses in crisis. What is more, companies that reduced the expenses before the crisis tended to contract them in the following period.

Figure 14. Percentage distribution of sample companies among contraction or accumulation strategies relating investments in employees, sequence of the three periods

Table 14 gives us an opportunity to judge what sequence of strategies relating expenses on employees was the most widespread. And we may conclude that the bi...


Подобные документы

  • Estimation of influence of economic growth, level of incomes of the population, the interest rate, inflation and exchange rate on company Hydrolife activity. Hydrolife Company the company which makes potable water and water with useful minerals.

    реферат [15,8 K], добавлен 31.01.2012

  • Economic growth and potential of economic system. The main problems of productive forces in Ukraine. Modern approaches to productivity. Productivity growth in industries. Improvements in infrastructure quality Support of employment of the population.

    курсовая работа [15,3 K], добавлен 09.05.2011

  • Features market forms of managing in the conditions of a rigid competition. Analysis a problem of internal diagnostics of the company and definition her strong and weaknesses, as well as the general characteristics of stages and role of his carrying out.

    реферат [17,4 K], добавлен 13.09.2010

  • The concept of economic growth and development. Growth factors: extensive, intensive, the growth of the educational and professional level of personnel, improve the management of production. The factors of production: labor, capital and technology.

    презентация [2,3 M], добавлен 21.07.2013

  • Current situation and market condition in which is Indes, offered services and company problems. Segmentation of the market and an industry condition. The analysis of possibilities and threats of firm, action for advancement of business processes.

    курсовая работа [21,5 K], добавлен 08.01.2012

  • Чтение и перевод текста "Economic growth". Ответы на вопросы к нему. Выбор правильного варианта слов, которыми необходимо заполнить пропуски в предложении. Определение правильности утверждений в английском тексте. Упражнение на составление словосочетаний.

    контрольная работа [10,7 K], добавлен 12.09.2013

  • Support of business entities on the part of specialized agencies of the state on world markets. Interconnection of economic diplomacy of Ukraine in international cooperation with influence on the results of foreign economic activity of the country.

    статья [30,1 K], добавлен 19.09.2017

  • The main principles of marketing. The globalization of activity and costs decreasing. The personification of interaction and transition to e-marketing and the problem of e-marketing economic effectiveness. Marketing communications in the internet.

    контрольная работа [29,3 K], добавлен 17.02.2011

  • Defining cognitive linguistics. The main descriptive devices of frame analysis are the notions of frame and perspective. Frame is an assemblage of the knowledge we have about a certain situation, e.g., buying and selling. Application of frame analysis.

    реферат [324,4 K], добавлен 07.04.2012

  • Economic system. List by hands-on and hands-off. Types of economic systems. Market economy. Mixed economy. Planned economy. Traditional economy. Participatory economics. Changes of an economic situation in Russia. Recent economic developments.

    реферат [15,0 K], добавлен 27.05.2007

  • Early Life. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Travels on the Continent. The Wealth of Nations. Society and "the invisible hand". Economic growth. After two centuries, Adam Smith remains a towering figure in the history of economic thought.

    реферат [13,4 K], добавлен 28.07.2004

  • The corporate development history and current situation strategy of the Computacenter. Opportunities and threats for Computacenter on the analysis of IT-industry and macro-environmental analysis. The recommendations for the future strategic direction.

    контрольная работа [27,5 K], добавлен 17.02.2011

  • 1997 year as turning point toward Russia’s economic stability. Major factors influence the onset and success of a speculative attack. Effects of the rise in interest rates. Components fueled the expectations of Russia’s impending devaluation and default.

    топик [14,7 K], добавлен 18.07.2009

  • Работа по английскому языку об экономике США. Выполнена на английском языке с дальнейшим переводом на русский язык. The basis of the US economy. Major industries. Agriculture. Foreign trade. Trade wars. Global economic influence. The balance of trade.

    реферат [15,6 K], добавлен 19.12.2008

  • Theory of economics was created and is developed by the economists of different schools. Main article: History of Economics. Areas of study. Techniques. Language and reasoning. Development of economic thought. The system of economic relations.

    реферат [22,6 K], добавлен 12.05.2008

  • Disintegration of the USSR. Restoration of Russia. Influence of the open market. The Asian financial crisis. Increase of local manufacture. Fast lifting of economy, gross national product. Export of consumer goods. Fluctuations in the world prices.

    топик [12,4 K], добавлен 04.02.2009

  • The first European currencies. Economic characteristics medium of exchange. The role of money in the society. Weakness of money in term of social measurement system. Money мarket fund price level. Japan direct investment in China. Returns of savings.

    реферат [885,4 K], добавлен 12.12.2011

  • Concept as a linguo-cultural phenomenon. Metaphor as a means of concept actualization, his general characteristics and classification. Semantic parameters and comparative analysis of the concept "Knowledge" metaphorization in English and Ukrainian.

    курсовая работа [505,9 K], добавлен 09.10.2020

  • Business situations. Company's Activities. Increase in use of the Internet. The analysis of requirements of buyers. Kinds of activity of campaign. Manufacturers of the goods, suppliers of the goods and services. Commercial services also are direct.

    лекция [11,4 K], добавлен 31.03.2009

  • Methodological characteristics of the adaptation process nowadays. Analysis of the industrial-economic activity, the system of management and the condition of adaptation process. Elaboration of the improving project of adaptation in the Publishing House.

    курсовая работа [36,1 K], добавлен 02.04.2008

Работы в архивах красиво оформлены согласно требованиям ВУЗов и содержат рисунки, диаграммы, формулы и т.д.
PPT, PPTX и PDF-файлы представлены только в архивах.
Рекомендуем скачать работу.