Concept, peculiarities of constitution and functions of civil society as a structural element of the modern world-system

Features of creation and arrangement of dimensions of civil society. Search for a new policy system. Functions of civil society in the European capitalist world economy. Consideration of the basics of world-system analysis of Immanuel Wallerstein.

Рубрика Политология
Вид статья
Язык английский
Дата добавления 13.07.2021
Размер файла 80,7 K

Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже

Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.

Размещено на http://www.allbest.ru

Concept, peculiarities of constitution and functions of civil society as a structural element of the modern world-system

Mykola Bulatevych

Abstract

The article proposes to look at civil society from the standpoint of Immanuel Wallerstein's world-systems analysis. Of course, Wallerstein can hardly be considered a theoretician of civil society. Still, his works can offer theoretical provisions that concern this topic as well. The article suggests the study of civil society as possibly the third structural element of the modern world-system, which, along with two other structural elements -- the axial division of labor and the state and the system of interstate relations, -- regulates social relations in it. It is shown that civil society consists of two dimensions: institutional and discursive. In general, features of creation and arrangement of each of these dimensions are characterized. The functions performed by civil society in the European capitalist world economy are highlighted.

Keywords: the modern world-system, civil society, the European capitalist world-economy, communicative action, Geoculture of the modern world- system, capitalist class, French Revolution, urban middle class, model of liberal state, surplus value, lower strata, ideology of liberalism

Анотація

civil society policy capitalist

У статті пропонується поглянути на громадянське суспільство з позицій світ-системного аналізу Імануїла Валерстайна. Звичайно, Валерстайна навряд чи можна назвати теоретиком громадянського суспільства. Однак в його роботах наявні теоретичні положення, які стосуються й цієї тематики. У статті запропоновано потрактування громадянського суспільства як можливо третього структурного елементу модерної світ-системи, який, разом з двома іншими структурними елементами -- осьовим поділом праці та державою і системою міждержавних відносин,-- впорядковує соціальні відносини в ній. Показано, що громадянське суспільство складається з двох вимірів: інституційного та дискурсивного. У загальних рисах охарактеризовано особливості створення та влаштування кожного з цих вимірів. Виокремлено функції, що їх виконує громадянське суспільство в європейській капіталістичній світ-економіці.

Ключові слова: модерна світ-система, громадянське суспільство, європейська капіталістична світ-економіка, комунікативна дія, геокультура модерної світ-системи, капіталістичний клас, Французька революція, міський середній клас, модель ліберальної держави, додаткова вартість, нижча страта, ідеологія лібералізму.

Introduction

This article is devoted to civil society as a subject of contemporary importance. This topic is widely developed in social sciences. Social scientists have created a number of theories of civil society, each of which offers its particular image. But many of such theories have one thing in common. Often civil society is considered in them as a structural element of a more general object -- a modern society, -- and depicted as emerging and developing within modern society. This feature is typical, for example, for the theory of civil society by Jurgen Habermas [19] or, for example, for Jeffrey Alexander's civil society theory [1] but also for other theories as well.

Immanuel Wallerstein in his world-systems analysis proposes a new object in the context of which social reality may be investigated. And this object is not a modern society, but -- a world-system. Wallerstein distinguishes several types of world-systems that existed in certain historical periods. But the modern world-system the American scientist calls as the European capitalist world-economy. The world-systems approach creates new perspectives for interpreting the essence of civil society. Although it is difficult to consider Immanuel Wallerstein as a civil society theoretician, nonetheless, in his scientific studies, it is possible to distinguish theoretical provisions that concern this topic as well. They give grounds to consider civil society as a structural element of the European capitalist world-economy and from this angle to interpret peculiarities of its constitution and functions it performs. Such an interpretation can enrich knowledge about civil society developed in social sciences.

Accordingly, the purpose of this article is: based on the theoretical provisions of Immanuel Wallerstein's world-systems analysis, in general terms to outline the concept, peculiarities of constitution and functions of civil society as a structural element of the modern world-system. Considering the limited space, this article is rather fragmentary and schematic. The theoretical basis for this work is the world-systems analysis by Immanuel Wallerstein. However, it still lacks some specific conceptual-categorical instruments relating to the subject of civil society. Therefore, in order to reveal peculiarities of constitution of civil society as a structural element of the modern world-system, the concept of communicative action is used in the work. It is borrowed from the theory of communicative action by Jьrgen Habermas, but it is used in the context of Wallerstein's world-systems analysis.

To reveal the subject of our study, the “structure -- action” construction would come in handy. Structures organize social action, preventing it from unfolding in a random way. They channel, more or less firmly, social action in a certain direction, and do not let it steer away from the required course. Structures are historical formations. According to Wallerstein, they occur at a certain historical moment, develop for a more or less long period, and at some moment, they die out [13, 3].

This article consists of four points: 1) the first point summarizes the concept and main features of civil society as a structural element of modern society; this generalization is needed in order to depart from it and move to understand civil society in a world-systems perspective; 2) the second point employs certain provisions of Immanuel Wallerstein's world-systems analysis as the basis to show the peculiarities of creating the institutional dimension of civil society; 3) the third point employs certain provisions of Immanuel Wallerstein's world-systems analysis and the concept of communicative action to review the features of the discursive dimension of civil society; 4) and finally, the fourth point deals with the peculiarities of inclusion of the lower strata of the modern world-system into civil society.

1. The concept and general features of civil society as a structural element of modern society

In social sciences, the essence of civil society is often contemplated within the confines of a territorially limited social unit termed as “modern society”. Civil society constitutes a structural element of this unit, distinct from its other two basic structural elements, economy and the state. Each of the three is interpreted as an autonomous sphere developing according to its own inner logic. On the one hand, economy, the state and civil society confront each other, but on the other hand, they supplement each other in their functions, thus stabilizing each other and forming the “systemic frame” of modern society [1, 31-33].

Economy is considered as a sphere of economic action. Within its framework, purposive-rational economic relations are ordered to create and distribute surplus value, or wealth. The state represents a sphere of administrative action. It features purposive-rational relations concerning distribution and exercising of administrative powers. Civil society is interpreted as a sphere of communicative action. This is a domain of communicative relations -- an open rational communication that has the purpose of achieving the mutual understanding or consensus about how to organize common, collective life based on universal principles of justice [9, 217-219; 10, 318-319].

Based on Nancy Fraser's work, we can distinguish the following features of civil society: it territorially coincides with legally defined boundaries of a certain modern society; as a result of communication, it produces public opinion addressed to the state that exercises sovereignty over this territory; the subjects of communication are members of a legally constituted political community -- nation, i.e. citizens of the state who can join voluntary nongovernmental and noncommercial associations, organizations and movements; every citizen has the same right to participate in communicative processes as other citizens; communication is implemented via national mass media, which connect territorially scattered participants with each other; communication requires the existence of a common linguistic medium: official language or several official languages [7, 10-12].

Civil society functions in a way that attracts attention to actions, events, states of affairs, etc. that, occurring in particular spheres of modern society, cause injustice. Citizens of the state “become outraged” and enter communicative networks of the public sphere to comprehensively discuss these actions, events and states of affairs in order to reach a consensus on the attitude to be displayed toward them and find the ways to fix the situation. As a result, civil society generates public opinion and uses it to put pressure upon administrative apparatus of the state and force the latter to adopt and carry out decisions aimed to restore justice. By participating in communicative processes of producing public opinion, citizens of the state become convinced that they have real influence upon organization of social relations in particular social domains. Society becomes for them their own “lifeworld” that they constitute for themselves, and the feeling of belonging to the same national community becomes stronger among them, thus strengthening social solidarity.

When conceptualizing the nature of civil society, it is important to establish when it has emerged, where and why. To ascertain these aspects, the concept of “European civilization” or simply “Europe” is often used in social sciences to define a historical-cultural formation that creates a single general cultural context for countries of the geographical region of Western Europe. As Andre Gunder Frank showed, an explanatory scheme is developed, according to which, European civilization rises in Ancient Greece and then passes a number of historical eras or stages in its development: antiquity, Hellenic-Roman, medieval, Renaissance, and early and late modernity [6, 3].

According to this scheme, the origins of civil society are also rooted in Ancient Greece. At that stage, it is its “protoform”. As European civilization has been developing, other protoforms of civil society have occurred in the context of subsequent eras. And only in era of early modernity did it begin to attain its present form. This explanatory scheme is often reproduced in works by social scientists. An example is works by the civil society historian John Ehrenberg [5] or the political scientists Steven DeLue and Timothy Dale [3]. The key factor that gave impetus to the emergence of civil society in early modern age was capitalism that was born at that time. The appearance of capitalism itself is also attributed to the cultural context of European civilization and traditionally explained, following Max Weber, by the effect of the ethics of ascetic Protestantism.

Speaking about particular countries of European civilization, civil society has first emerged in England and France in the 17th century, because capitalism was beginning to spring up in these particular countries. The terms denoting the new communicative sphere were coined at that very time: English “civil society” and French “la societe civile” [19, 46]. How does capitalism give rise to civil society? To ensure rational functioning, capitalism needs to institutionalize itself in the relevant social structures of the society. At the time of its birth, these were nonexistent in the “still-feudal” world of the 16th -- 17th centuries. Therefore, having been born in England and France, capitalism set in motion modernization processes in the “traditional” societies of these countries. It caused rationalization and differentiation of these societies, and as a result, old feudal structures started to gradually come down and give way to new, separating from each other, basic structures necessary for the capitalist order: modern economy, the state and civil society. Social transformations in England and France continued for several hundreds of years, completing only in the mid-19th century. A rational form of capitalism and the corresponding modern societies with differentiated economy, the state and civil society gained a firm foothold in these countries.

In other countries of European civilization, social changes were launched somewhat later, depending on when a particular country began to switch to the “capitalist footing”. In Germany, for instance, it began in the 18th century. And by the early 20th century, in Max Weber's opinion, countries of Europe have completed the transition to rational capitalism and saw the rise of developed modern societies in their territory [18, 255]. The French Revolution played an important role in these processes by helping eliminate obsolete feudal social structures and entrench new, modern ones.

After modernization of European countries finished, capitalism began to be considered not a unique phenomenon rooted in the culture of European civilization but a universal factor of successful development. As Wallerstein shows, there was now a belief that it could be implemented in any place of the world, even if the required cultural context was absent there. All an undeveloped country had to do is to start the necessary reforms and begin developing a European-like capitalism, and that would immediately set in motion modernization processes resulting, at the end of the day, in the establishment in that country of a developed, rationalized modern society [13, xviii].

However, there were instances when in certain countries the processes of capitalist modernization were launched but then curbed at certain point, for one reason or another, or when their “catching-up” modernization had from the very beginning an alternative, “non-capitalist” character. In those instances, developing a rational capitalism is not possible. In the societies of these countries, the three base modern structures do seemingly appear, but their sufficient differentiation could not be achieved. There is often a situation when the state towers above the other two spheres, intruding on them and subordinating them to the logic of its development. Countries like that see the establishment of a nondemocratic (e.g. authoritarian or totalitarian) political regime. Private sector-driven market economy begins to degenerate, and the functioning of civil society is defined and controlled by the state, which is manifested, in particular, in the control by the state of the topics for communication and of the arguments that should be used in that communication.

If a country begins transition to capitalism and moves toward development of the necessary social structures but transformations have not been completed yet, there might be another situation in which the economy towers above the other base spheres of action and subordinates them to the logic of its development. Under these conditions, the country sees the establishment of a not-quite-rational form of capitalism, the so-called “wild capitalism”. The state is reduced to the minimum, performing only the limited functions of a “nightwatch”. Communication in the civil society domain becomes fragmentary and reified under the pressure from an uncontrolled and unregulated market, and the mechanisms for communicative producing of public opinion fall apart. In both cases of insufficient differentiation -- when either the state or economy dominates over the other two spheres -- civil society cannot be considered sophisticated. Free rational communication in it degrades, the possibility of achieving mutual understanding in a communicative way becomes more difficult, and social solidarity weakens.

Immanuel Wallerstein proposes orientation not toward the modern society but toward a more global object -- world-system. The scholar calls the modern world-system a European capitalist world-economy. It has emerged in Europe during the “long 16th century”, went through several waves of territorial enlargement since then, and eventually, encompassed the entire world. A world-economy has many political units and cultures within it, and daily life of people in it is substantially different, but at the same time, it remains an integral formation knit on the basis of single economy. The underlying systemic principle for development of the world-economy is infinite accumulation of capital [17, 85-86].

A world-economy consists of two structures. The first is the axial division of labor. According to Wallerstein, it contains three production regions characterized by an uneven degree of development: core, semiperiphery and periphery. The axial division of labor orders economic action within a world- economy. The production region of periphery creates conditions for directing economic action into the channel of producing raw materials with low surplus value, while in the core region, it is directed into manufacture of industrial high-tech products with high surplus value. In this respect, the semiperiphery occupies an interim place between the other two. After exchanging the core's industrial high-tech products for the periphery's raw materials, surplus value flows, with intermediation of the semiperiphery's “conveyor belts”, to the core and accumulates there. That's how the mechanism of exploitation by core countries of the workforce and raw materials of periphery countries is formed, with simultaneous strengthening of the latter's underdevelopment [13, 86-87, 116, 219].

The other structure of a world-economy is represented by states and interstate blocs where administrative action takes place. Core countries have strong states that maintain the domination of the core over the periphery. They facilitate uneven redistribution of surplus value among production regions. At the same time, core states wage a continuous struggle among them for the right to exploit the periphery and control the semiperiphery. Peripheral countries have weak states that have little to confront “core” states with. Their role is being reduced to the balancing of the local budget and maintaining social order in the territory they control. Based on these two structures, elites of “core” states become able to appropriate the overwhelming proportion of surplus value produced in a world-economy [14, 113-116].

Considering peculiarities of the constitution of the modern world-system, Wallerstein is talking only about two structures of that system: 1) axial division of labor and 2) modern states and interstate system. Still, the world- systems analysis of the American scholar contains theoretical provisions that give reasons to think about whether civil society can be considered the third structure of a world-economy. According to its definition, civil society is a sphere in which communicative action is institutionalized. And if it indeed is the third structure of the modern world-system, communicative action in it must be institutionalized in a way that does not contradict the logic of the world- economy's development: communication in civil society must promote, directly or indirectly, infinite accumulation of capital.

Wallerstein's approach may have some consequences for the interpretation of historical development of civil society. The concept of “European capitalist world-economy” is ill-aligned with the concept of “European civilization”. If we are to imagine social world as a world-economy, then, firstly, it would be economy that brings social world's components into a single whole, not a single cultural context. And secondly, the beginning of this world is dated to the “long 16th century” and not earlier. Social worlds that existed in the geographical region of Europe before the appearance of the world-economy can be regarded as other, distinct historical systems rather than development phases of the single whole called “European civilization”. Therefore the view claiming that civil society is inalienably related to the development of “European civilization” and traces its origins to Ancient Greece does not look convincing.

On the other hand, the concept of “European civilization” does not take into account development specifics of communicative sphere in other regions of the world. There are studies showing that, for example, in Imperial China under the Ming and Qing dynasties, this sphere was more developed than in contemporary Europe. For instance, Karla Simon [11], Michael Edwards [4, 255], Kathryn Bernhardt, Philip Huang and other scholars [2] describe not only a great diversity of voluntary organizations in Chinese cities, such as public hospitals, market associations, cultural groups, public homes for the elderly, etc. that were cared for by the townspeople themselves, but also the existence of elements of the legal system that regulated their activity. In all likelihood, communicative relations existing in the public space between economy and the state can be found in any developed historical system; they just take a different shape in each of them. One can assume that in the modern world-system, they take the shape of civil society.

The other consequence is reinterpretation of the reasons for the emergence of civil society. In his world-systems analysis, Wallerstein shows that capitalism is an attribute of a world-economy, not of particular units that form it. A world- economy is what's capitalistic, not the countries existing within it. What we can say about these countries is that they are, for instance, more developed or less developed, depending on the place each of them occupies in the axial division of labor: in the production region of core, semiperiphery or periphery. Capitalism cannot be built in a separate country, and therefore, it cannot be a factor directly responsible for the appearance of modern society in a particular country, of which civil society is an inalienable structural element. If we are to adhere to this view, sophistication or unsophistication of civil society in a particular country should be explained by other factors.

From the standpoint of Wallerstein's world-systems analysis, the answers to the questions of the time, place and reasons for emergence of civil society become more precise. A modern civil society has emerged between 1789 and 1848 in core states of the modern world-system. Since the world-economy emerge during the “long 16th century” and civil society has appeared in the late 18th -- early 19th century, it appears that the world-economy has successfully existed without this structure for almost three hundred years and did not need it for its development. Why then has civil society emerged, after all? An indirect cause was, of course, development of the European capitalist world-economy, but the event directly responsible for its emergence was the French Revolution.

In social sciences, civil society can be considered consisting of two interrelated dimensions: institutional and discursive. This approach is employed, for instance, by Jeffrey Alexander [1, 69]. The institutional dimension is related to social institutes that create conditions for deployment of open communication in the society, while the discursive dimension to the cultural knowledge, codes and symbols used directly during communication. When taking a look at civil society from the standpoint of world-systems analysis, this approach can be used as the basis to describe its constitution. But now, the specific features of both the institutional and discursive dimensions would be interpreted somewhat differently.

2. The French Revolution and the establishment of the institutional dimension of civil society

The French Revolution was, undoubtedly, an event that significantly changed today's world. Social sciences offer enough explanations of its meaning, causes and effects. A distinguishable feature of Immanuel Wallerstein's version is the consideration of the French Revolution in the context of development of the modern world-system. As follows from the very definition of the European capitalist world-economy, the French Revolution could not, by its very essence, be “bourgeois” in the sense that it caused, or at least accelerated, the transition from feudalism to capitalism, because at the time it broke out, capitalism has been successfully functioning for quite a while.

Randall Collins showed that thanks to the efforts from Theda Skocpol, Charles Tilly, Jack Goldstone and other scholars, an explanatory model has been developed, citing intra-elite conflict that results in a collapse of the state as the main reason for modern revolutions. According to this model, a revolution always starts “on the top”, among the elite. In order for it to happen, two key factors must coincide. The first is fiscal crisis of the state: the state finds itself in a situation when it is no longer able to pay foreign debt or finance its own army, police and security forces. Fiscal crisis is often caused by military reasons: exuberant military expenditures and battlefield defeats. However, it becomes fatal when combined with the other factor -- a split among the elite as regards the way out of the difficult situation. When an intra-elite conflict escalates to the point when any agreements and at least the minimal consensus become impossible, the state machinery becomes paralyzed and the monopoly for the legitimate use of force falls apart. That opens the door to the spontaneous popular uprising and the overthrow of the ruling regime [12, 57-58].

Overall, Wallerstein's description of the French Revolution fits into the aforementioned model. However, the context of the modern world-system is added. A world-economy is developing in a way that, on the one hand, it goes through a number of economic upturns and downturns explained by Kondratyev's theory of long cycles, and on the other hand, hegemon states appear within it from time to time. The latter play an important role in its development, being capable of ensuring relative stability and order in a world-economy, but their hegemony does not last long. When a hegemon steps down, a fight for the vacant position ensues. From that moment on, the order in a world- economy becomes shaky. A long period of disorder and turbulence begins, featuring protracted world wars.

According to Wallerstein, after the United Provinces of the Netherlands lost the status of hegemon in 1675 the struggle between Great Britain and France for hegemony began, culminating in the Seven Years' War. France was defeated in that war, which essentially meant losing the struggle. And in the early 19th century, Great Britain became a hegemon state of the modern world- system. For France, the consequences of the defeat were severe. Its position in the world-economy became worse. The loss of key colonies combined with large military expenditures undermined France's financial strength. The balance between revenues and expenditures was upset, and the country was forced to borrow more and, thus increasing its sovereign debt. As of 1788, the costs of servicing sovereign debt have reached 50% of the country's budget, and the state has found itself on the verge of bankruptcy [15, 84-85].

Wallerstein shows that in the early 1770s, French elites (although the American scholar was talking mostly about the capitalist class, attaching somewhat lesser significance to other elite groups) began to look for ways to improve the difficult financial situation. Two competing options have been proposed. Capitalists-manufacturers saw the most effective solution in the substantial increase of taxes levied upon agricultural enterprises of capitalists- landowners. These taxes were traditionally low, for the latter enjoyed tax benefits guaranteed by their nobility status. On the other hand, capitalists- landowners opposed the implementation of any mechanisms that could redistribute their profits in favor of the state. They saw the way out of crisis in liberalization of trade. Capitalists-landowners have managed to lobby a trade agreement with Britain, signed in 1786. According to that agreement, France opened its domestic market to British industrial goods, while Britain opened its market to French agricultural products. They hoped to replenish public finances with customs receipts from duties levied upon imported industrial goods. However, no substantial improvement of financial situation could be achieved [15, 86-88].

Instead, the position of capitalists-manufacturers has worsened as they have been squeezed out by British competitors from not only foreign markets but even France's domestic market. Capitalists-manufacturers were unceasingly pressuring the state, demanding drastic measures: promoting stronger their interests within the world-economy, substantially enlarging the tax base, erecting customs barriers to protect local manufacture and trade against foreign competition. On the contrary, capitalists-landowners opposed restrictive economic and trade measures and measures aimed to strengthen the state, rejecting the raise of taxes and insisting upon continuing liberalization. They have even been seriously thinking about the option of rolling France back to the semiperiphery, considering the possibility of the country's partial deindustrialization [15, 89-92].

By 1789, France's public finances have reached the critical condition. Yet, no program of getting out of this situation could be developed. At some moment, exasperated by acute fiscal crisis, the intra-elite conflict has reached the highest point of escalation. The state became dysfunctional. The mechanisms of the legitimate use of force malfunctioned, and a vacuum of power has appeared in the society. The dam was destroyed, and the waves of broad masses poured into the breach -- a revolution in France has begun. And the rising masses of people-- the lower strata and urban middle class -- appear at the historical stage.

The broad masses have directed their revolutionary energy toward radical redistribution of surplus value in their favor. The masses wanted to destroy the world-economy's structures and mechanisms that made infinite accumulation of capital possible. Therefore, Wallerstein believes, the French Revolution had an anti-system, not “bourgeois” nature. Since the explosion has occurred in a key core state, the legitimacy of the world-economy faltered and revolutionary uprisings began spreading over the countries of both the core and other production regions.

In the course of the French Revolution, the rising masses demanded to shift the locus of sovereignty from the monarch to the people. In practice, that meant transformation of the state from an absolute monarchy to a popular democracy. If these demands were met, the broad masses would have received control over the state and, along with it, real instruments for redistribution of surplus value, while the capitalist class would have lost both the power and the possibility to continue accumulating capital infinitely. On the one hand, the capitalist class had to heed to demands of the rising people. But on the other hand, they could not allow the establishment of a popular state. To find the way out of this problematic situation, the capitalist class had, Wallerstein believes, to show wits and inventiveness. They had to design a model of the state that would appear popular at first glance while not actually being such, but even then enjoying support from a substantial part of the population, and the establishment of such a state would have calmed down the revolutionarily- spirited population. The historical solution was to create the model of liberal state, which eventually replaced the absolute monarchy [16, 23].

The arguments cited by Wallerstein give reasons to assume that the model of liberal state envisages the establishment of not only a modern liberal state allegedly facing the people but also civil society. Open communication in the sphere of civil society enabled the public to legally exert influence over the state, compelling the latter to take certain measures. On its part, the state was becoming accountable to civil society, orienting toward its demands; decisions made by the state had to conform to the will of the people. This was the scheme through which the “popular” nature of the new model of state had to be realized. But in fact, this model made possible only a limited participation in the discussion of a quite narrow range of local matters. The implementation of this model did not change the position of the capitalist class and did not alter the fundamental principles on which a world-economy is developing. Still, it did receive the support from the people, or at least from their key part, urban middle class.

The establishment of a new model of state began with constitutional and electoral reforms in core states. The adoption of constitutions limited the monarch's powers, while enfranchisement of the people enabled them to elect legislative bodies of the state. The next step was introduction of broad civil rights. The equality before law, freedom of movement and choice, freedom of speech, expression, conscience, religion and belief, freedom of association and freedom of information -- all these liberties made possible public discussion of contemporary political, economic and other matters. Reforms led to the creation of the foundation for the model of liberal state -- the nation of citizens.

The establishment of the model of liberal state was accompanied by the de-facto constitution of civil society's institutional dimension, which became the foundation for open public communication. A number of civil society institutes can be named. The first important institute is public opinion, the production of which was legally enabled and legislatively regulated. The second institute is, probably, the liberal state, which is subjected to communicative pressure from public opinion and must react to it. A modern civil society could hardly be able to function without the existence of a liberal state. Free and independent mass media enabling communications to circulate across the entire society and expanding the public sphere should be included to civil society institutes as well. The system of civil rights, and especially the right to vote, is also worth mentioning. Perhaps, it makes sense to include to civil society institutes voluntary associations, organizations, parties, etc. legally established by citizens and legislatively regulated.

Development of the new model was distinguishable for the fact that at first, electoral and civil rights have been unequally granted to the urban middle class and the lower strata. Emmanuel-Joseph Sieyes proposed to differentiate between “active” and “passive” citizens. In his opinion, all people living in the country had to have the right to life, the right to protection of their person and property, the right to freedom. However, not everyone should have the right to form bodies of public administration and participate in open communication in the civil society sphere, i.e. not all are “active” citizens. According to Sieyes's terminology, only representatives of the urban middle class have the status of “active” citizens [16, 145].

Having gained the right to vote and the right to legally participate in communicative processes of producing public opinion, the urban middle class became confident that they really have influence upon organization of social life and that they do determine the direction of its development. They abandoned revolutionary practice, making themselves comfortable within the new sociopolitical order of “modern society”. After that, uprisings of the lower strata lost their edge and no longer posed a serious threat. Without network and organizational resources of the urban middle class, anti-system rebellions of the lower strata had little chances to succeed. The only thing left for the lower strata was to be content with the questionable status of “passive” citizens [16, 73-75].

According to Wallerstein, the establishment of the model of liberal state in three core countries of the European capitalist world-economy: Britain, France and Belgium, was completed in 1830-1832 [16, 74-75]. The urban middle class became the main adept and support of this model. At first, only representatives of this class were included to civil society as full members or participants. The model of liberal state provided structural stability to the modern world-system and restored its lost legitimacy. The new model became a template for political changes, and over time, it was implemented, to a greater or lesser degree of success, everywhere within the modern world-system.

3. Geoculture of the modern world-system and the discursive dimension of civil society

The creation of institutional dimension enabled to organize and to order circulation of public communication streams in society. However, the institutes themselves were not enough. In order to establish communication, the very communication between citizens must be channeled in a certain direction. For that purpose, the second-- discursive-- dimension of civil society must be constituted in a special manner. Any communication is based on a language, and language, in turn, is deeply interwoven into the cultural environment of a community and is formed in it. Therefore, the discursive dimension of civil society requires the existence of a special language of communication and the relevant cultural context. Wallerstein's world-systems analysis does not have enough instruments that could be used to study the discursive dimension, but Jьrgen Habermas's theory of communicative action does -- it's the concept of communicative action. It can be used to perceive the discursive dimension of civil society while adhering to the world-systems view at social reality.

Jьrgen Habermas has developed the notion of communicative action to cognize the domains of social reality that Max Weber's attention missed. Habermas understands communicative action as a special type of social action. It is realized in a dialogue and takes the form of linguistic utterances in which the actors or participants of dialogue are trying to reach mutual understanding as regards something in the world and coordinate their behavior on that basis. Acting communicatively, every participant offers an own vision of the problematic situation being discussed, criticizes the vision of others and defends his own vision against objective criticism, and that goes on until all actors arrive at the common definition of situation. In communicative action, mutual understanding is achieved on the basis of rational argumentation: a participant may drop his own interpretations and accept interpretations proposed by others not because of external coercion but voluntarily, yielding to the power of better arguments [9, 10-13].

When trying to reach mutual understanding, actors always assume relation to something in the world. Habermas offers a decentered understanding of the world, dividing it into three formal domains: objective world of existing states of affairs, social world of the community of which the participants of dialogue are members, and subjective world to which only one person has privileged access. Acting communicatively, actors may refer in their utterances to things from one or another world: to objective facts of nature, to social norms and values of the community, or to their own subjective experiences. The three worlds distinguished by Habermas represent differentiated segments of the knowledge used in communication [9, 52].

If, during communication, an actor assumes relation to the objective world, his communication is represented, according to Habermas, by constative utterances in which he refers to facts and represents the existing state of affairs. An actor states something about the physical world of nature, and is able to defend the truthfulness of his utterances in the light of objective criticism. Truth becomes the criterion for evaluation of utterances: other actors may accept or decline a statement on the basis of whether or not it represents the true state of affairs. If an actor assumes relation to the social world of the community whose member he is, his communication would then be represented by regulative utterances. In these utterances, he refers to social norms and values and establishes interpersonal relationships with other members of the community. An actor puts forth the imperatives regarding how others should conduct themselves, or defends the conformity of his own behavior with the community's legitimate norms. In that case, normative rightness becomes the criterion for evaluation of utterances. And finally, if an actor assumes relation to his own subjective world, he makes expressive statements referring to his personal subjective experiences and presents his self to others. An actor is trying to create a certain image of himself in eyes of the public by randomly revealing his own subjectivity. The criterion for evaluation of utterances in this case is sincerity [9, 85-88, 90-93].

According to Habermas, communicative action envisages language as a medium for free communication, in which actors simultaneously refer in their linguistic utterances to things in the objective, social and subjective worlds in order to establish a common definition of the situation and reach mutual understanding this way. Acting communicatively, actors integrate the three worlds into a single coordinate system that provides them with the knowledge for interpretations. They simultaneously refer to objective facts, social norms and values, and subjective experiences and mutually put forth validity claims for the truth, normative rightness and sincerity. Ideally, communication should produce an inter-subjective meaning of the world that is the same for all participants [9, 93-95].

The social world plays an important role in the daily communication practice. In their interpersonal relationships, actors continuously face problematic and often conflict situations that require resolution. The resolution takes place via the reference to the social norms and values legitimate for the particular community. If actors assume relation to the social world in daily communication, their communication may be channeled into two different discourses. Habermas calls the first of them a “discourse of application”. In it, the participants of communication refer to social (in particular, moral) norms without thematizing them [8, 67-68].

The second discourse unfolds in a situation when actors thematize and discuss the norms per se, trying to arrive at the common understanding of these norms or to establish new norms. In that case, actors refer in their arguments to the social values that are significant for the community. Interpreting, establishing or abolishing a particular (including legal) norm is possible on the basis of values. The latter lay at the core of social norms that regulate daily behavior in the social environment. Habermas calls this discourse a “discourse of justification”. It is important that values must be internalized by every member of the community and transformed into internal structures of his conscience. A communicative establishment, interpretation or abolition of a norm within the “discourse of justification” may be possible only under this condition, and a proposal to act in accordance with a particular social norm as part of the “discourse of application” will not be construed as external coercion [8, 67-68].

Communicative always occurs in the horizon of lifeworld. Daily communicative practice takes place against the background of lifeworld, and in turn, lifeworld is reproduced via interpersonal communication. One cannot exist separately from the other. Habermas understands lifeworld as the context for the processes of achieving mutual understanding, as the background for thematizing and discussing particular problematic situations in daily life. The German scholar distinguishes three structural components of lifeworld, terming them as “culture”, “society” and “personality”. For Habermas, “culture” means the stock of knowledge from which participants of communication draw interpretations; “society” means legitimate orders through which the participants regulate their membership in a social community and reproduce social solidarity; and “personality” means competencies enabling the subject to speak and act, i.e. enabling him to participate in the processes of achieving mutual understanding [10, 135-138].

Since civil society is defined as an institutionalized sphere of communicative action communication in civil society takes place according to the rules of that action. Citizens of the state communicate in order to achieve mutual understanding on the basis of rational argumentation. They broadly use the knowledge from all three worlds, referring in their utterances to facts, social norms and values, and subjective experiences, mutually raising validity claims for the truth, normative rightness and sincerity. However, civil society is a special sphere. Communication in it is somewhat different from the one taking place in ordinary daily life. In civil society, the purpose of communication is to achieve understanding regarding not simply narrow, limited “routine” problematic situations but also bigger matters-- the matters of rational, correct organization of society in general and its certain domains in particular. Therefore, relation to the social world and the use of appropriate knowledge play the key role in this respect. But the very stock of that value-based normative knowledge to which citizens could refer must be special.

On the other hand, the model of liberal state was designed to become implementable in any core, semiperipheral or peripheral state. This model became standard, or template, for countries of the modern world-system after the French Revolution. Since civil society is established along with the establishment of a liberal state, it must be standard, too. It must be characterized by the same attributes, regardless of the world-economy country in which it occurs. It means that besides standard social institutes, the value-based normative stock of knowledge or, in Habermas's words, the component of lifeworld called “society”, must the same everywhere, too. No matter what production region of the modern world-system a country is located in, no matter what its cultural specifics are, what language its people speak and what religion they follow, but if this country adopts the model of liberal state, it must see the establishment of a standard value-based normative cultural context that enables standard communication in the civil society domain. And first of all, we are talking about the uniform set of values that must be internalized by the country's people.

It appears that Geoculture of the modern world-system was responsible for ensuring such a uniform value-based normative filling of the discursive dimension. It created the same stock of knowledge about the social world, or “society” component of lifeworld, for civil societies of any country of a world- economy adopting the model of liberal state. In Wallerstein's opinion, Geoculture of the modern world-system is the ideology of liberalism. It shaped itself up in the course of the French Revolution, and has finally gained foothold before 1848. Geoculture contains a system of values that are essentially ideological. They include, first of all, freedom, equality and justice, and a number of other, derivative values, in particular, tolerance, dignity, individual autonomy, development of human abilities, etc. Geoculture of the modern world-system enabled to transcend cultural and religious specifics of the population of any country and create in that country, along with the relevant social institutes, a standardized, modern rational community: civil society.

Regardless of what matters of the society's constitution citizens were trying to reach understanding on in the public sphere, they would refer in their expressions to the standard set of values of the “common social world”.

It results in relative standardization of communication itself. It becomes sufficiently defined or canalized, flowing in a more or less defined direction. The channeling of communication also manifests itself in the fact that a person referring to alternative values may be labeled “uncivil” and, in the best-case scenario, pushed back to the “periphery” of civil society or, in the worst case, expelled from it. When communication concerning the constitution of society takes place, a predetermined set of values helps build, regardless of the region of a world-economy, approximately the same image of a properly-organized rational society: open, just, equal, etc. It must be oriented at in civil communication. The actually existing societies are still far from this image, so they have to be “approximated” to that image on the basis of civic engagement and activity.

Geoculture of the European capitalist world-economy enabled to standardize communication in the civil society domain, bringing communication to a “common denominator”. So now, public communication in civil society of any country of the modern world-system was taking place in a more or less the same way, according to the same rules. Overall, the establishment of the model of liberal state convinced the urban middle class that they have received real control over the state and the ability to influence decisions the state makes. They were assured that they now have an efficient instrument of improving the existing, still imperfect society.

...

Подобные документы

  • Functions of democracy as forms of political organization. Its differences from dictatorship and stages of historical development. Signs and methods of stabilizing of civil society. Essence of social order and duty, examples of public establishments.

    контрольная работа [24,4 K], добавлен 11.08.2011

  • Analysis of Rousseau's social contract theory and examples of its connection with the real world. Structure of society. Principles of having an efficient governmental system. Theory of separation of powers. The importance of censorship and religion.

    статья [13,1 K], добавлен 30.11.2014

  • The term "political system". The theory of social system. Classification of social system. Organizational and institutional subsystem. Sociology of political systems. The creators of the theory of political systems. Cultural and ideological subsystem.

    реферат [18,8 K], добавлен 29.04.2016

  • Study of legal nature of the two-party system of Great Britain. Description of political activity of conservative party of England. Setting of social and economic policies of political parties. Value of party constitution and activity of labour party.

    курсовая работа [136,8 K], добавлен 01.06.2014

  • Women predominate among graduates in the fields of health, education and society and culture. The K. Betts-Robert Birrell bunch's anti-migration version of the "new class" theory. Racism is not innate in "human nature". Why Betts and company can't win.

    эссе [78,5 K], добавлен 24.06.2010

  • The situation of women affected by armed conflict and political violence. The complexity of the human rights in them. Influence of gender element in the destruction of the family and society as a result of hostilities. Analysis of the Rwandan Genocide.

    реферат [10,9 K], добавлен 03.09.2015

  • The definition of democracy as an ideal model of social structure. Definition of common features of modern democracy as a constitutional order and political regime of the system. Characterization of direct, plebiscite and representative democracy species.

    презентация [1,8 M], добавлен 02.05.2014

  • Basis of government and law in the United States of America. The Bill of Rights. The American system of Government. Legislative branch, executive branch, judicial branch. Political Parties and Elections. Freedom of speech, of religion, and of the press.

    презентация [5,5 M], добавлен 21.11.2012

  • Leading role Society Gard Kresevo (USC) in organizing social and political life of the Poland. The Polish People's Movement of Vilna Earth. The influence of the Polish Central Electoral Committee. The merger of the TNG "Emancipation" and PNC "Revival".

    реферат [18,3 K], добавлен 02.10.2009

  • Referendum - a popular vote in any country of the world, which resolved important matters of public life. Usually in a referendum submitted questions, the answers to which are the words "yes" or "no". Especially, forms, procedure of referendums.

    презентация [1,2 M], добавлен 25.11.2014

  • The rivalry between Islam and Chistianity, between Al-Andalus and the Christian kingdoms, between the Christian and Ottoman empires triggered conflicts of interests and ideologies. The cultural explanation of political situations in the Muslim world.

    реферат [52,8 K], добавлен 25.06.2010

  • Review the controversial issues of the relationship between leadership and hegemony in international relations, especially in the context of geostrategy of the informal neo-empires. The formation of a multipolar world order with the "balance of power".

    статья [64,7 K], добавлен 19.09.2017

  • The classical definition of democracy. Typical theoretical models of democracy. The political content of democracy. Doctrine of liberal and pluralistic democracy. Concept of corporate political science and other varieties of proletarian democracy.

    реферат [37,3 K], добавлен 13.05.2011

  • Barack Hussein Obama and Dmitry Medvedev: childhood years and family, work in politics before the presidential election and political views, the election, the campaign and presidency. The role, significance of these presidents of their countries history.

    курсовая работа [62,3 K], добавлен 02.12.2015

  • The foundations of the constitutional system of the Russian Federation. The civil society as the embodiment of balance of private and public interests. Legal and functional character of the civil society. Institutional structure of constitutional system.

    реферат [19,5 K], добавлен 07.01.2015

  • Civil society and the rule of Hegel: the philosophical meaning. The relationship of civil society and the state. Main problems in the writings of Hegel. A phases in the history of political and legal ideas. Function state. The sign of civil society.

    реферат [18,2 K], добавлен 25.12.2012

  • Overview of civil law system. History of appearance and development of the Roman-German legal family. General characteristics of civil law legal system. Sourses of the right. Distinctive features of the system. Soubgroups in the civil law system.

    курсовая работа [36,7 K], добавлен 10.08.2011

  • The history and legal significance of "de facto marriage" in Russia. The study of value-family relations in the cell of society. Consideration of the sociological methods of investigation of the phenomenon of civil marriage in the Russian society.

    реферат [24,4 K], добавлен 13.09.2010

  • Constitutionalism as political and legal theory and practice of development of the constitutional democratic state and civil society. Principles of modern constitutional system of board. Role of society in the course of formation of municipal authority.

    реферат [18,5 K], добавлен 07.01.2015

  • The Constitutional Court about political parties and religious organizations as institutes of the civil society. The party political component of the constitutional system as the subject of the constitutional control. Creation of regional parties.

    реферат [24,9 K], добавлен 14.02.2015

Работы в архивах красиво оформлены согласно требованиям ВУЗов и содержат рисунки, диаграммы, формулы и т.д.
PPT, PPTX и PDF-файлы представлены только в архивах.
Рекомендуем скачать работу.