The cost of empire’ unity in late imperial Russia

Average annual government revenue and expenditures in 1892-1895 and average annual direct taxes per capita in 1886-1895 by groups of provinces in Russia, excluding Siberia, Finland, and Central Asia. Rating of the regions by administrative expenditures.

Рубрика История и исторические личности
Вид статья
Язык английский
Дата добавления 09.08.2021
Размер файла 69,4 K

Отправить свою хорошую работу в базу знаний просто. Используйте форму, расположенную ниже

Студенты, аспиранты, молодые ученые, использующие базу знаний в своей учебе и работе, будут вам очень благодарны.

Размещено на http://www.allbest.ru/

Article

The cost of empire' unity in late imperial Russia

Mironov, Boris Nikolaevich - Dr. Sc. of Histore, Professor, Saint-Petersburg State University, Saint Petersburg, Russia

Резюме

Миронов, Борис Николаевич - доктор исторических наук, профессор, Санкт-Петербургский государственный университет, Санкт-Петербург, Россия,

Правительство постоянно беспокоилось о «цене империи», которую понимало как финансовые издержки за удержание какой-либо окраины в составе государства. Министерство финансов вычисляло цену как разницу между государственными расходами на содержание администрации и войск, обустройство границ и городов, проведение железных дорог, а также других затрат от казны, с одной стороны, и бюджетными доходами от всех налогов и прибылей, которые государственное казначейство получало, - с другой. Проблема цены империи и ее единства имеет экономическое измерение, но не сводится к экономическим выгодам и потерям. С точки зрения империи, огромную роль играли вопросы ее безопасности, военной, экономической и геополитической власти, мессианизм, культурное и религиозное преобладание, решение внутренних политических проблем, легитимация власти императора, престиж верховной власти и государства и другие.

Окраины оценивали «цену» империи со своей точки зрения и также учитывали нематериальные факторы. Степень защищенности, мера цивилизаторской миссии Центра, опасность ассимиляции и утраты этнической идентичности, возможность этнокультурной автономии и др. Однако оценить нематериальные факторы намного труднее и главное - проблематичнее, потому что точки зрения Центра и периферийных регионах различались и консенсус найти часто невозможно. Отношения между Центром и окраинами Российской империи были столь разнообразными, многосторонними и динамичными, что подвести их под какую-то одну формулу или один сценарий невозможно. Этнополитология предлагает три схемы для описания природы отношений центра и периферии: концепции гегемонии, внутреннего колониализма и диффузионизма. Чаще всего российское правительство проводило политику гегемонии и интеграции. Элементы колониализма встречались на ранних этапах освоения окраин. Тесная административная, правовая и экономическая интеграции на основе взаимных выгод постоянно находилась в центре его внимания. Но главная цель верховной власти и его правительства состояла в сохранении целостности империи. Ради этого они готовы были идти на любые жертвы со стороны русских. Однако в экстремальных случаях требовали и со стороны других народов империи поступиться своими интересами.

Ключевые слова: Российская империя, концепция гегемонии, концепция внутреннего колониализма, концепция диффузионизма, цена империи, факторы единства империи, политика относительно окраин, центр и окраины, экономическая история, социальная история

The cost of Empire' unity in Late Imperial Russia

Mironov, Boris Nikolaevich - Dr. Sc. of Histore, Professor, Saint-Petersburg State University, Saint Petersburg, Russia

Abstract: The government constantly fretted over the “cost of empire”, which it understood as the expense of possessing any borderlands as part of the state. The Ministry of Finance calculated the cost as the difference between state outlays for the maintenance of its administration and armed forces, the construction of borders and towns, and the installation of railways, as well as other expenses from the treasury, on the one hand, and budget revenue from all taxes and income the treasury received, on the other. The problem of the cost of empire and the empire's unity, however, is not confined to economic gains and losses. From the empire's point of view, the issues that played a huge role were the empire's security, its military, economic, and geopolitical power, messianism, cultural and religious predominance, the resolution of internal political problems, the legitimization of the emperor's rule, the prestige of the supreme authority and the state, and other matters. For their part, the borderlands assessed the cost of empire and also took non-material factors into account: the degree of security, the extent of the center's civilizing mission, the danger of assimilation and of the loss of ethnic identity, the desire for ethno-cultural autonomy, and others. Appraising the intangible factors is much more difficult and, above all, more problematic, because the perspectives of the center and the peripheral regions differ and it is often impossible to find consensus. The relationship between the center and the borderlands of the Russian empire was so varied, multifaceted, and dynamic that to express it through a single formula or scenario is impossible. The field of ethnopolitics offers three several such schemes to describe the nature of relations between the center and the periphery: the concept of hegemony, of internal colonization, and of diffusionism. Analysis of the center's relations with the borderlands in the imperial period shows that at various times and in various regions all three scenarios have been realized, but most often the government followed the concepts of hegemony and diffusion. Occasionally, one encounters elements of colonialism in the early stages of the acquisition of the borderlands. Close administrative, legal, and economic integration on the basis of mutual advantages continuously lies at the center of the government's attention. But the main purpose of the supreme authority and its government consisted of preserving the integrity of the empire. For this reason, they were prepared to make any sacrifices on the part of the Russians. In extreme cases, however, they required that other peoples of the empire also sacrifice their own interests for a time.

Keywords: the Russian empire, the cost of empire, the concept of hegemony, the concept of internal colonization, the concept of diffusionism, the factors of unity of the Empire, the policy regarding margins, economic history, social history

Alternative perspectives concerning the significance of the Russian center in the economic development of the periphery exist in the historiography. According to one point of view, the metropole devoured the resources of the ethnic borderlands in order to secure its own prosperity and consequently hampered the periphery's development. A second view holds that the periphery prospered by absorbing the center's resources. Similar discussions about other European empires take place in Western historiography. Since decades, the costs and profits of the Habsburg, the French, the Spanish, the Ottoman or the Portuguese empires and, far more developed the British empire, are highly debated, and different authors oppose the costs and benefits of the empires, according to the sources, the period, the methods of calculation. Discourse on the cost of empire in late imperial Russia was an extremely vital matter. For example, during the work of the Special Conference on the Needs of Agricultural Industry in 1902-1905, twelve local committees of experts sharply criticized the government for the inequitable allocation of taxes, in their view, among the regions: “Central Russia bears the largest tax burden, while disbursements from state resources are carried out first and foremost in the borderlands, which is one of the chief causes of the impoverishment of the center”. “The borderlands exhaust the center's wealth. The country is turning into a funnel. The wellbeing of its separate parts is lower, the farther they are from the periphery, the closer they areto the center”. The outflow of vitality and material resources to the borderlands and industrial regions creates a distinct, depressed situation in the heart of Russia, especially in the milieu of noble landownership. In its relationship with its borderlands Russia stands in stark contrast to other countries. All states expand their possessions for quite specific purposes: either so that the territory recently being acquired can provide a new tax base and revenue for the metropole, or the territory is needed as a new market for the sale of products; but one way or another colonies and acquired territories in all states nourish the metropole and serve as a rich source of income for it. England serves as a vivid example in this respect. In Russia the situation is exactly the opposite: there is no borderland region that has not cost the country enormous sums. Even Finland costs the state no small amount of money, to say nothing of the Asian possessions. One can compare Russia in its relation to its borderlands to a “mother, nursing her children from her own breast”. The borderlands have been placed in an especially privileged position not only with respect to the expenditure of the central government's resources upon them. Manufacturing industries develop primarily in the borderlands and the capital cities. Any protection and assistance provided for the sale of agricultural products from the borderlands through the establishment of differentiated tariffs also entails extremely burdensome competition for the agricultural center and its outdated methods. The abundance of virgin land and the ease and low cost of production along with the advantageous tariff give the borderlands the opportunity to unload grain on the market at low prices, at a direct loss to the native oblasts of Russia. I shall examine these points of view as hypotheses and try to verify them.

The periphery of the Russian empire really did enjoy several advantages in its development when compared with the central Great Russian regions thanks to tax exemptions, freedom from military conscription, and a favorable geographic position on the border or by the sea. The government constantly fretted over the “cost of empire”, which it understood as the expense of possessing any borderlands as part of the state. The Ministry of Finance calculated the cost as the difference between state outlays for the maintenance of its administration and armed forces, the construction of borders and towns, and the installation of railways, as well as other expenses from the treasury, on the one hand, and budget revenue from all taxes and income the treasury received, on the other. With this approach the situation in 1892-1895 appeared as follows (Table 1).

Table 1 - Average annual government revenue and expenditures in 1892-1895 and average annual direct taxes per capita in 1886-1895 by groups of provinces in Russia, excluding Siberia, Finland, and Central Asia

Group of provinces*

Population, in thousands

Revenue, in thousands of rubles**

Expenditures,

in thousands of rubles**

Revenue per capita,

in kopecks

Expenditures

per capita, in kopecks

Difference, in kopecks

Direct taxes per capita,

in kopecks

10 in the Kingdom of Poland

9,443

99,425

48,069

10.53

5.09

5.44

1.35

3 Baltic

2,386

46,143

14,634

19.34

6.13

13.21

1.73

6 Ukrainian

17,221

130,827

64,611

7.60

3.75

3.85

1.27

Bessarabia

1,936

8,919

5,443

4.61

2.81

1.80

1.42

7 Lithuanian- Belorussian

11,676

50,493

53,187

4.32

4.56

-0.24

1.14

6 Caucasus

5,995

40,983

48,442

6.84

8.08

-1.24

0.79

3 Pre-Caucasus

3,729

13,465

11,616

3.61

3.12

0.49

0.53

3 Black Sea

6,282

72,073

37,654

11.47

5.99

5.48

1.49

39 provinces in all***

58,668

462,328

283,656

7.88

4.83

3.05

1.22

30 Great Russian provinces****

52,578

388,706

195,306

7.39

3.71

3.68

1.72

St. Petersburg

2,105

208,520

394,600

99.06

187.46

-88.4

7.21

31 Great Russian provinces in all

54,683

597,226

589,906

10.92

10.79

0.13

1.91

70 provinces in all

113,351

1,059,554

873,562

9.35

7.71

1.64

1.55

Source: Calculated from Antropov A. P.Finansovo-statisticheskiy atlas Rossii, 1885-1895. St. Petersburg, 1898. Appendices, tables 1-4.

* The grouping of provinces in P. A. Antropov's atlas: Polish: Warsaw, Kalish, Petrokov, Lomzha, Plotsk, Suvalki, Liublin, Kelets, Radom, Sedlets; Baltic: Kurland, Livonia, Estland; Ukrainian:Volhynia, Kiev, Podolia, Poltava, Kharkov, Chernigov; Lithuanian-Belorussian: Vilna, Vitebsk, Grodno, Kovno, Minsk, Mogilev; Caucasus: Baku, Elizavetpol, Dagestan, Kutais, Tiflis, Yerevan; Pre-Caucasus: Kuban, Stavropol, Terek; Black Sea: Ekaterinoslav, Taurida, Kherson.

** “Revenue” includes all forms of state revenue (direct and indirect taxes, redemption payments, customs duties, regalia, timber and mining income, and so forth), while “expenditures” signifies all forms of government disbursements (on administration, the army, and the like). Direct taxes include redemption payments.

*** With primarily a non-Russian population.

**** With primarily a Russian population.

Let us ascertain which regions required more expenditures and brought greater returns to the treasury, defining public spending as expenditures on administration or as capital invested in administration, while defining state revenue as income from investments in administration or as the degree of exploitation of the regions (Table 2).

Source: Calculated from the data in Table 2. * Excluding St. Petersburg province.

government russia administrative expenditure

Table 2 - The rating of the regions by administrative expenditures and gross profits, 1892-1895 (kopecks per capita)

Group of provinces

Treasury

expenditures

Group of provinces

Treasury

profits

Bessarabia

2.81

3 Pre-Caucasus

3.61

3 Pre-Caucasus

3.12

7 Lithuanian-Belorussian

4.32

30 Great Russian

3.71

Bessarabia

4.61

6 Ukrainian

3.75

6 Caucasus

6.84

7 Lithuanian-Belorussian

4.56

30 Great Russian

7.39

39 non-Russian provinces

4.83

6 Ukrainian

7.60

10 in the Polish Kingdom

5.09

39 non-Russian provinces

7.88

3 Black Sea

5.99

10 in the Polish Kingdom

10.53

3 Baltic

6.13

3 Black Sea

11.47

6 Caucasus

8.08

3 Baltic

19.34

St. Petersburg

187.46

St. Petersburg

99.06

70 provinces in all

7.71

70 provinces in all

9.35

Table 3 - The rating of the regions by net profits on administrative expenditures, 1892-1895

Group of provinces

Net profit to the treasury, in kopecks per capita

Group of provinces

Rate of return for the treasury, %

3 Pre-Caucasus

0.49

St. Petersburg

-47

Bessarabia

1.8

6 Caucasus

-15

39 non-Russian provinces

3.05

7 Lithuanian-Belorussian

-5

30 Great Russian provinces*

3.68

3 Pre-Caucasus

16

6 Ukrainian

3.85

39 non-Russian provinces

63

10 in the Kingdom of Poland

5.44

Bessarabia

64

3 Black Sea

5.48

3 Black Sea

91

3 Baltic

13.21

30 Great Russian provinces

99

7 Lithuanian-Belorussian

-0.24

6 Ukrainian

103

6 Caucasian

-1.24

10 in the Kingdom of Poland

107

St. Petersburg

-88.4

3 Baltic

215

70 provinces in all

1.64

70 provinces in all

21

The state invested 23 percent more in the thirty-nine non-Russian provinces than in the thirty Great Russian provinces, while it received from these provinces only 6 percent greater gross profits (state revenue) per capita. Consequently, the rate of return to the treasury on its investment in the administration of the thirty Great Russian provinces (not including St. Petersburg province, in effect the city of St. Petersburg, where numerous military units and the bureaucracy were located because of the city's status as the capital) proved to be 36 percent higher than in the thirty-nine non-Russian provinces (Table 3).

Table 4 - The balance of state revenue and expenditures by groups of provinces in 1868-1890 (millions of rubles)

Group of provinces

1868-1877

1878-1887

1888-1890

St. Petersburg

-121.272

-197.325

-227.230

Moscow

1.227

18.438

48.078

Finland

-2.404

-4.652

-

Northern

4.603

3.923

4.843

Eastern

13.4187

18.056

18.764

Central-Industrial

22.208

26.148

35.632

Central-Black Earth

47.858

56.474

70.627

Little Russian

9.835

13.803

21.447

Baltic

7.454

14.905

24.194

Northwestern

0.668

-1.436

1.667

Southwestern

12.140

22.448

31.293

Southern

14.414

21.963

50.890

Caucasus

-26.029

-30.496

-19.435

Polish

0.540

6.808

21.224

Western Siberia

1.991

2.815

0.569

Eastern Siberia

-2.145

-5.940

-5.653

Turkestan

-4.769

-6.120

-3.774

Source: Calculated from Iasnopolskii N. P. O geograficheskomraspredeleniigosudarstvennykhdokhodoviraskhodov v Rossii: Opytfinansovo-statisticheskogoissledovaniia. Prilozheniya: Statisticheskietablitsy, kartogrammyidiagrammy. Kiev, 1897. Tables 40-41, 44-45.

* The grouping of provinces as designated by Iasnopolskii N.PCapital provinces (St. Petersburg, Moscow); Northern provinces (Arkhangelsk, Vologda, Novgorod, Olonets, Pskov); Eastern provinces (Viatka, Kazan', Orenburg, Perm, Samara, Ufa); Central-industrial provinces (Vladimir, Kaluga, Kostroma, Nizhegorod, Smolensk, Tver', Iaroslavl'); Central-blackearth provinces (Voronezh, Kursk, Orel, Penza, Riazan, Saratov, Simbirsk, Tambov, Tula); Little Russian provinces (Poltava, Khar'kov, Chernigov); Baltic provinces (Kurland, Livonia, Estland); Northwestern provinces (Vilna, Vitebsk, Grodno, Kovno, Minsk, Mogilev); Southwestern provinces (Volhynia, Kiev, Podolia); Southern provinces (Astrakhan, Bessarabia, Don, Ekaterinoslav, Tavrida, Kherson); North Caucasus provinces (Stavropol'); Caucasus provinces (Baku, Tiflis); Polish provinces (Warsaw, Kalish, Petrokov, Lomzha, Plotsk, Suvalki, Liublin, Kelets, Radom, Sed- lets); Western Siberian provinces (Tobol'sk, Tomsk, the Governorate General of the Steppe); Eastern Siberian provinces (Amur, Yenisei, Trans-Baikal, Irkutsk, Primorsk, Iakutsk); Turkestan.

The data on state revenue and expenditures for 1892-1895 demonstrates that the government did not at all hamper the development of its borderlands and did not shift the burden of administrative costs to these regions. On the contrary, by means of financial mechanisms the government established preferences for the borderlands at the expense of the Great Russian provinces. These preferences diminished over time, however, which led to a reduction in the budget deficits of the non-Russian provinces and an increase in the treasury's rate of return on investment. Data for 1868-1890 provides evidence for this, according to which the deficits in the borderlands during these years were larger than in 1892-1895 (Table 4).

The situation in 1879-1881 becomes more clearly visible after converting state revenue and the treasury's expenditures into per capita terms: the Belorussian, Lithuanian, Pre-Caucasus, Caucasus, and Siberian provinces and Turkestan had deficits; the Polish provinces were practically self-sufficient and hence brought no profit to the treasury (Table 5).

Table 6 gives an even more vivid picture, demonstrating that the rate of return on state investments from 1879-1881 to 1892-1895 increased everywhere.

Considering the approximate nature of the initial information, one need not interpret the data presented here literally (that is, by what percentage returns increased). The data demonstrates a trend attributable to the policy the state pursued from the 1880s to equalize the tax burden on the regions' population. The leveling of the tax burden is visible more graphically at the provincial level. The coefficient of variation serves as one of the best indicators of the differentiation. In 1879-1881 the coefficient of variation for state income (the treasury's revenue on its expenditures on administration) in seventy provinces equaled 83 percent, while in 1892-1895 it amounted to 49 percent, that is, it decreased 1.7 times.

Table 5 - Average annual state revenue and expenditures by groups of provinces in Russia in 1879-1881 (kopecks per capita)

Groups of provinces

Treasury revenue

Treasury expenditures

Rate of return, %

Capitals

28.58

82.25

-65

Northern

4.33

3.27

32

Eastern

3.92

2.20

78

Central-Industrial

5.16

2.91

77

Central Black-Earth

5.20

5.13

1

Little Russian

4.90

4.04

21

Baltic

10.85

3.52

208

Northwestern

4.00

5.67

-29

Southwestern

6.48

3.52

84

Southern

7.74

6.71

15

North Caucasus

3.42

4.77

-28

Transcaucasus

2.39

11.36

-79

Polish

6.78

6.71

1

Siberian

4.62

4.97

-7

Turkestan

1.55

4.36

-64

The reduction in preferences for the regions sparked their displeasure. For example, attempts to align and equalize the contributions from Poland and Finland to the central state budget (by increasing their share of military expenditures to the level of other borderland entities) were perceived by them as a colonization policy.

Table 6 - The treasury's rate of return on “investments” in administration per capita by groups of provinces in 1879-1881 and 1892-1895 (percent)

Provinces

1879-1881

1892-1895

St. Petersburg

-65

-47

6 Caucasus

-79

-15

7 Lithuanian-Belorussian

-29

-5

3 Pre-Caucasus

-28

16

Finland

1

30

3 Black Sea

15

91

6 Ukrainian

51

103

10 Vistula Land

1

107

3 Baltic

208

215

Sources: Calculated from Antropov P. A.Finansovo-statisticheskiy atlas... Appendices, tables 1-4; Iasnopol 'skiy N. P. O geograficheskomraspredelenii. Appendices, tables 40-41,44- 45.

From 1892 to 1895, the Caucasus and the western region (the Belorussian-Lithuanian provinces), along with the steppe region of Central Asia and Turkestan, proved to be a financial drain on the empire. In the remaining “borderlands” state revenue exceeded public expenditures. In other years, however, regional budgets showed a surplus. Over a twenty-four-year period in the Caucasus, from 1855 to 1879, fifteen years had a budget surplus and nine years a budget deficit. A small aggregate surplus of 6.9 million rubles over the twenty-four years and a rather low rate of return on treasury investments (5.5 percent) show that the region became self-sufficient (Table 7).

In 1883, the director of the Baku treasury chamber, A. A. Pushkarev, at the behest of the Minister of Finance Nikolai Kh. Bunge, presented “observations on all the economic and financial issues of the Transcaucasus region”. According to Pushkarev, inhabitants of the Transcaucasus paid four times less when compared with the amounts paid by residents of Novgorod or Pskov province; at the same time, a muzhik from the northern provinces was obliged to pay for the Transcaucasus residents, as it were, to meet all the budget requirements of civil administration, excluding military expenditures, not covered by local revenue. Inhabitants of Novgorod and Pskov provinces did in fact pay higher taxes, but their taxes were approximately one-third greater: in 1878-1881, they paid 3.79 rubles per capita, while the Caucasus residents paid 2.78 rubles.

Table 7 - Revenue and expenditures in the civil administration budgets of Transcaucasuskrai, 1855-1880 (rubles)

Year

Revenue

Expenditures

Balance

Year

Revenue

Expenditures

Balance

1855

3,739,455

3,640,189

99,266

1868

5,228,309

5,799,662

-571,353

1856

4,816,969

4,025,263

791,706

1869

6,132,364

6,288,281

-155,917

1857

4,895,777

3,669,785

1,225,992

1870

6,189,627

6,580,196

-390,569

1858

5,312,256

4,265,105

1,047,151

1871

5,241,702

6,233,374

-991,672

1859

3,056,710

2,508,218

558,492

1872

5,831,533

5,744,421

87,112

1860

2,993,374

2,808,103

185,271

1873

8,803,333

6,244,879

2,558,454

1861

3,014,068

3,055,648

-41,580

1874

6,505,354

6,684,829

-179,475

1862

3,299,055

3,079,141

-219,914

1875

6,539,646

6,745,616

-205,970

1863

2,595,867

2,991,532

-31,665

1876

7,492,059

6,622,750

869,309

1864

3,543,762

3,538,239

5,523

1877

7,122,199

6,650,107

472,092

1865

3,883,522

3,630,757

252,765

1878

8,754,259

7,163,364

1,590,895

1866

4,200,967

3,922,402

278,574

1879

8,765,157

8,632,236

132,921

1867

4,237,874

4,767,770

-529,896

Total

132,195,198

125,291,867

125,291,867

Source: Esadze S. S.IstoricheskayazapiskaobupravleniiKavkazom: in 2 vols. Tiflis, 1907. Vol. 2. P. 306-307.

In 1883, the director of the Baku treasury chamber, A. A. Pushkarev, at the behest of the Minister of Finance Nikolai Kh. Bunge, presented “observations on all the economic and financial issues of the Transcaucasus region”. According to Pushkarev, inhabitants of the Transcaucasus paid four times less when compared with the amounts paid by residents of Novgorod or Pskov province; at the same time, a muzhik from the northern provinces was obliged to pay for the Transcaucasus residents, as it were, to meet all the budget requirements of civil administration, excluding military expenditures, not covered by local revenue. Inhabitants of Novgorod and Pskov provinces did in fact pay higher taxes, but their taxes were approximately one-third greater: in 1878-1881, they paid 3.79 rubles per capita, while the Caucasus residents paid 2.78 rubles.

Turkestan was included among the “unprofitable” regions up to 1908, when for the first time since 1868 the treasury received a slight profit that exceeded its expenditures by 1.6 percent. One can consider the surplus a dividend on the state's investment in Turkestan. The profit rate rose over four years, from 1908 to 1911, and increased to a considerable extent (to 14.8 percent), but in 1912 it declined to 7.7 percent; and from 1913 the regional budget again ran deficits (Table 8).

Table 8 - State expenditures and revenue for Turkestan Krai in 1868-1916 (rubles)*

Year

Expenditures

Revenue

Balance"

Year

Expenditures

Revenue

Balance**

1868

3,791,795

-

-

1892

9,085,855

7,089,831

-22.0

1869

4,597,971

1,884,193

-59.0

1893

9,956,277

8,053,723

-19.1

Т870

5,757,442

1,974,430

-65.7

1894

9,873,573

8,096,818

-18.0

Т87Т

6,366,160

2,003,944

-68.5

1895

10,970,117

7,834,481

-28.6

Т872

7,655,961

1,940,157

-74.7

1896

10,606,971

9,174,288

-13.5

1873

8,131,229

2,508,939

-69.1

1897

13,909,528

9,894,879

-28.9

1874

7,994,430

2,667,650

-66.6

1898

12,272,367

8,941,033

-27.1

1875

8,739,240

2,554,310

-70.8

1899

11,422,013

7,730,622

-32.3

1876

9,834,405

3,623,050

-63.2

1900

12,916,447

8,778,749

-32.0

1877

9,834,453

3,533,757

-64.1

1901

12,931,138

9,302,964

-28.1

1878

11,757,425

3,661,654

-68.9

1902

20,706,765

10,180,928

-50.8

1879

11,434,484

3,985,786

-65.1

1903

21,965,508

11,756,168

-46.5

1880

13,661,633

3,988,204

-70.8

1904

26,267,973

13,299,560

-49.4

1881

-

-

-

1905

23,837,915

13,234,511

-44.5

1882

-

5,526,889

-

1906

16,071,656

15,406,947

-4.1

1883

-

-

-

1907

16,728,371

16,260,246

-2.8

1884

-

6,494,090

-

1908

16,086,622

16,342,690

+1.6

1885

-

-

-

1909

16,456,628

17,588,401

+6.9

1886

-

6,678,362

-

1910

18,358,413

20,105,457

+9.5

1887

9,144,546

6,058,978

-33.7

1911

18,907,297

21,698,123

+14.8

1888

9,773,573

6,468,172

-33.8

1912

20,625,094

22,217,285

+7.7

1889

9,342,759

5,984,228

-36.0

1913

23,162,602

23,049,257

-0.5

1890

8,318,827

6,609,741

-20.5

1914

-

23,704,087

-

1891

10,229,785

8,568,116

-16.2

1915

38,094,184

-

-

1916

-

13,548,446

-

Source: Statisticheskiyezhegodnik [Turkrespubliki], 1917-1923 gg.: in 2 vols. / D. P. Krasnovskiy (ed.). Tashkent, 1924. Vol. 2, pt. 3. P. 380.

*The years with a surplus appear in boldface.

** As a percentage of the amount of expenditures. A “minus” sign signifies a deficit, and a “plus” sign a surplus.

The treasury began to receive a net gain from the region only in the fortieth year after the annexation of Turkestan, after spending 194 million rubles, almost 5 million rubles per year without hope of a return for thirty-nine years. If one compares this data with the amount of land, the land area, and its value in other borderlands of the empire, “Turkestan gives the treasury four times less than other parts of the State, relatively speaking”, according to the Chief Director of Land Management and Agriculture in 1912, Aleksandr V Krivoshein.

Nikolai P Iasnopol'skii, in his landmark three-volume work on data from 1868-1890 convincingly demonstrated the existence of an unequal tax burden for various regions of Russia to the benefit of the borderlands: “It is mainly the interior of the territory of European Russia that finds itself more heavily taxed through all the state levies, when compared to its economic resources, than almost all the regions external to it and the capital provinces”. P. A. Antropov, another leading scholar of provincial state budgets, also reached a similar conclusion.

The Grand Duchy of Finland had its own autonomous budget. It contributed to imperial military outlays by agreement with the Russian government and maintained the administration of the Governor-General of Finland. Its regular state revenue always exceeded expenditures, however. Nevertheless, it always carried state debt of less than the sum of two years of state revenue (Table 9).

The per-capita contributions of the duchy toward the empire's military expenses were always lower than those from the rest of the empire. In 1896, military expenditures in Russia, excluding Finland, constituted 27.4 percent of all regular state spending, but in Finland they were 16.1 percent; in 1907 these outlays were 21.4 percent and 0.2 percent, respectively; in 1910, 23.2 and 8.2 percent respectively; and in 1913, 25.8 and 8.9 percent. On average during the years 1896-1913, the percentages were 25 and 6.

State expenditures, that is, investments in the thirty-nine non-Russian provinces, were greater than in the Great Russian provinces - 4.83 rubles versus 3.71 rubles. This ensured an additional financial flow (funds designated for payment for services and for the procurement of locally produced goods for the army stationed there) from the center to the provinces settled by non-Russian populations and gave the center the opportunity to avail itself of these resources to satisfy its own needs. Regional budget shortfalls in the Belorussian-Lithuanian and Caucasus regions resulted from their position on the empire's border. The central government expended significant sums on the army, which stimulated the economic development of these regions. The deficit in St. Petersburg province stemmed from the large outlays on the central administration, the court, the army, and the Guard.

Table 9 - State revenue and expenditures of the Grand Duchy of Finland and its public debt in 1877-1921 (Finnish markka per capita)

1877-1890

1891-1904

1905-1913

1914-1917

1918-1921

Population, in thousands

2151.6

2589.2

3027.6

3280.8

3343.2

State revenue

19.13

30.40

51.35

82.35

429.43

State expenditures

18.10

25.18

40.85

65.69

369.20

Government debt

31.92

38.44

52.90

60.22

489.44

Military expenditures*

15.2

9.4

4.6

8.0

17.7

State debt as a percentage of annual revenue

167

126

103

73

114

Source: Calculated from Annuairestatistique pour la Finlande [1877-1921]. Helsingfors, 1878-1922. *Military expenditures as a percentage of regular state expenditures.

The approach of the Ministry of Finance concerning state finances and the budget makes a great deal of sense. Measuring the true “cost of empire” requires a more sophisticated and complex calculation, however. First, the methodology used by the Ministry of Finance combined all the military expenses the state incurred in a province (region [raion]) in their entirety together with its outlays in this province (or region). Consequently, the frontier provinces found themselves overburdened with military expenditures not by virtue of their annexation and the need to maintain an additional military contingent there to keep order, but strictly because of their location on the border. When a Russian province was located on the border, it had to host large military forces and bear the costs of maintaining them, as was observed, for example, in St. Petersburg province (for which reason the province was considered unprofitable and the beneficiary of state subsidies). It is inaccurate to charge all military outlays for annexed provinces on the border, in their entirety, at any rate, to the account of these provinces. As Governor-General of Turkestan Aleksandr B. Brevskii rightly pointed out in his report to the tsar in 1898, expenditures on the armed forces stemmed from national, not local, exigencies, since this krai was a border region. Had Turkestan not become part of the empire, the state would have had to maintain troops in Siberia and Orenburg krai, as had been the case earlier. Inasmuch as at that time Turkestan already made possible a reduction of up to forty million rubles in payments just for cotton despite the lack of convenient transportation routes (thereby promoting the strengthening of the ruble), additional payments to support the military cannot be considered as deficit spending in the state economy. And if one excludes military expenditures, then no border region in the post-reform era was unprofitable. Even Turkestan, excluding the disbursements for the Ministry of War, began to show a profit as early as the years 1868-1874: in these years Turkestan furnished the treasury with 6.5 percent of the returns on the total state budget outlays. Spending on railway construction as well as on maintaining the army in border regions also should not be attributed entirely to the latter, since this spending benefited not only the incorporated krai but also the Russian territory and, ultimately, the center and the whole empire. For example, in Turkestan, in Vrevskii's view, precisely because of the growing state spending on railway construction a substantial increase in cotton exports occurred, as well as an upsurge in the incomes of the local population.

Finally, in calculating the “cost of empire” one must take into account not only state but also private spending and revenue (that of individuals and non-governmental corporations and organizations). In this case one should take into account the net profits of trade, manufacturing, transport, and financial enterprises, for this income doubtlessly existed - otherwise they all would have become bankrupt - as well as the net proceeds immigrants and the indigenous population obtained through the krai's development under Russian influence and aid. In addition, it is necessary to consider the multiplier or cumulative effects of investment in the development of the Central Asian economy, especially in cotton cultivation, because besides the direct, primary effect in terms of national revenue and employment, investments generate indirect or tangential secondary, tertiary, and subsequent effects. Unfortunately, such calculations are never made. In this instance it is evident: the “cost of empire” was lower and the preponderance of revenue over expenditures began significantly earlier than was apparent exclusively from the flow of public funds. Moreover, both the indigenous population and colonists received the benefits of economic growth.

The Grand Duchy of Finland presents a convincing example of obtaining economic benefits from affiliating with Russia. The century spent as a part of Russia was a period of prosperity for the Finns. Between 1809 and 1917 the population increased 3.5 times (from 863 thousand to 3 million). At the time of the duchy's declaration of its independence, only about six thousand Russians lived there continuously (0.2 percent of the country's population), while Swedes constituted 12.9 percent. Great strides were made in the economy, culture, art, literature, and education. The Finnish economy's growth rate surpassed the average Russian and European rates. The average annual per-capita growth rate of GDP in 1870-1913 (years for which comparable data exist) increased 0.79 percent more rapidly than in the empire as a whole and 0.02 percent faster than in all of Europe (Table 10).

In Finland the preconditions for rapid economic development had emerged, thanks in part to the large share of expenditures that could go toward public services and popular education, compared with the empire as a whole, and the much lesser proportion spent on military needs and debt repayment. The Russian market played a significant role in Finland's economic development: its share of the duchy's trade volume in various years equaled from 30 to 50 percent. The economic expansion in Finland continued up to the beginning of the First World War. Now, as to the matter of the alleged exploitation of the borderlands by the “metropole” and the depletion of their resources: In the early twentieth century the Commission to Investigate the Question of the Dynamics of the Rural Population's Welfare in the Central Agricultural Provinces from 1861 to 1901 Compared with Other Localities in European Russia (hereafter, the Commission of the Center) was active, having been established on November 16, 1901, at the initiative of Finance Minister Sergei Iu. Witte.

Table 10 - Gross domestic product (GDP) per capita in Europe and the United States of America (1990 international dollars*)

GDP per capita

Growth rates of GDP per capita

1870

1913

1937

1950

1870-1913

1913-1937

1913-1950

The Russian Empire

1097

1551

2267

2827

0.934

1.016

1.019

Finland

1290

2288

3638

4362

1.013

1.020

1.011

Poland

-

1739

1915

2447

-

1.004

1.009

Denmark

1929

3768

5601

6404

1.016

1.017

1.008

Norway

1370

2454

4180

5376

1.014

1.022

1.012

Sweden

1247

2806

4565

6539

1.019

1.022

1.014

Central and Eastern Europe

1437

2250

2720

3016

1.010

1.008

1.008

Europe

1686

2643

3217

3579

1.011

1.008

1.008

USA

2445

5301

6430

9561

1.018

1.008

1.009

Sources: Calculated from Maddison A. World Population, GDP and Per Capita GDP, 1-2008 AD (Groningen Growth and Development Centre).Access Modehttp://www.ggdc.net/MADDISON/oriindex.htm (last visited - May 2019); Broadberry S. Aggregate and Per Capita GDP in Europe, 1870-2000: Continental, Regional and National Data with Changing Boundaries.Access Modehttps://www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/users/Broadberry/EuroGDP2.pdf (27 October 2011; File: EuroGDP2) (last visited - July 2017).

* 1990 International Geary-Khamis dollars.

The commission's task was defined as follows: the collection of statistical materials describing comprehensively the development of agriculture after the abolition of serfdom in the fifty provinces of European Russia over a period of forty years, from 1861 to 1900. More than one hundred specialists participated in the research effort. Working through the Department of Direct Taxes of the Ministry of Finance over the course of two years, experts collected, processed, and in October 1903 printed the most complete digest of largely unpublished information from departmental and, to some extent, zemstvo statistics. The first part of the work included data on the state of the peasant economy in each of the fifty provinces from 1861 to 1900, grouped into twelve regions by twenty-six characteristics: population (population size, marriage rate, birth rate, death rate, natural increase), migration, military conscription and marriages to soldiers, budgets, vodka consumption, the trends of savings bank deposits, land under cultivation, the size of l...


Подобные документы

  • Причины и предпосылки военного конфликта 1894-1895 гг. Обстановка перед войной. Соотношение сил сторон. Ход военных действий. Итоги войны. Начало раздела и финансового закабаления Китая империалистическими державами. Японская колониальная империя.

    дипломная работа [51,3 K], добавлен 05.02.2007

  • Эволюция русско-японских отношений: царская политика в регионе, зарождение конфликта (1895-1905 гг.), роль ведущих империалистических держав в его развитии, война; Портсмутский мирный договор. Предпосылки сближения России и Японии, военный союз 1916 г.

    магистерская работа [158,3 K], добавлен 25.03.2011

  • Анализ основных причин реформирования губернского уровня власти для Западной Сибири. Структура и организация Тобольского губернского управления в 1895-1917 годах. Функции и состав канцелярии губернского управления. Полномочия высших должностных лиц.

    дипломная работа [921,1 K], добавлен 12.09.2016

  • Description of the economic situation in the Qing empire. State control over the economy. Impact on its development Opium Wars. Thermos trade policy of the government. Causes and consequences of the economic crisis. Enforcement of a foreign sector.

    курсовая работа [77,7 K], добавлен 27.11.2014

  • Fedor Kachenovsky as a chorister of "the choir at the court of Her Imperial Majesty Elizabeth" in St. Petersburg. Kachanivka as "a cultural centre" and it's influence on creation of writers of Ukraine and Russia. Essence of Tarnovsky’s philanthropy.

    доклад [18,2 K], добавлен 29.09.2009

  • Russia Empire in the XX century entered into a complex economic and political environment. Consequences of defeat of autocracy in war with Japan. Reasons of growing revolutionary motion in Grodno. Events of revolution of a 1905 year in Byelorussia.

    реферат [9,4 K], добавлен 14.10.2009

  • Russian history: the first Duke of Russia; the adoption of Christianity Rus; the period of fragmentation; battle on the Neva River with Sweden and Lithuania; the battle against the Golden Horde; the reign of Ivan the Terrible and the Romanov dynasty.

    презентация [347,0 K], добавлен 26.04.2012

  • The formation of the Bund as the organization was laid union of the circles of the Jewish workers and artisans Russia empire, basis of the organizational structure. Creation of striking funds. Evolution of the organizational structure of the Bund.

    статья [8,6 K], добавлен 14.10.2009

  • Поздний период Цинской империи: опиумные войны. Война с Францией, Тайпинское восстание. Японо-цинская война 1894—1895 гг., закабаление Китая; тройственная интервенция; успехи русской политики. Революция 1911-12 гг., коммунистическое движение "4 мая".

    презентация [3,8 M], добавлен 21.11.2012

  • Политика "самоусиления" (1861-1895 гг.), особенности этапов ее проведения. Внешняя политика Китая в последней трети XIX в. Характеристика "ста дней" реформ. Начало политической деятельности Сунь Ятсена. Первый этап движения Ихэтуаней (1898-1899).

    реферат [29,9 K], добавлен 10.02.2011

  • Политика "самоусиления" правительства Цин (1864-1895 гг.). Положение Китая в конце ХIХ в. и главные реформы Кан Ювэя (1898 г.). Последствия попыток модернизации для страны. Теория Ж.Ж. Руссо в работе Лян Цичао. Семь принципов китайских революционеров.

    дипломная работа [69,9 K], добавлен 14.12.2015

  • Политическая обстановка в Японии после 1868 года. Движение за свободу и народные права. Агрессивная внутренняя и внешняя политика правящих классов. Причины и последствия Японо-китайской войны 1894-1895 гг. Япония в период перед Первой мировой войной.

    курсовая работа [41,9 K], добавлен 08.02.2011

  • Движение за реформы в Корее и политика России в условиях обострения японо-китайского соперничества. Японо-китайская война 1894-1895 гг., политика России. Российско-корейское сотрудничество после японо-китайской войны. Российско-корейские культурные связи.

    курсовая работа [62,4 K], добавлен 29.03.2012

  • "Болгарский кризис" 1886-1887 годов, внутри- и внешнеполитическое положение Болгарии, укрепление ее суверенитета. Провозглашение независимости Болгарии и экономическое развитие страны. Участие Болгарии в Балканских войнах, развитие болгарской культуры.

    курсовая работа [49,6 K], добавлен 09.02.2011

  • Формирование городского самоуправления г. Воронежа в 1870 1892 гг., введение Городового положения. Влияние реформы 1892 г. на городскую управу и её социальный состав. Организация работы управы и губернской администрации, делопроизводство канцелярии.

    курсовая работа [53,5 K], добавлен 21.11.2010

  • What is Civilization. Ancient Western Asia, before Civilization. Who Were the Hurrians. Mesopotamian Civilization, ancient Sumer. Digging in the Land of Magan. The Code of Hammurabi. Laws of Babylon, Egyptian Civilization, the Akkadian Kingdom.

    учебное пособие [161,7 K], добавлен 04.02.2012

  • Традиции городского самоуправления в России. Формирование городского самоуправления г. Воронежа в 1870-1892 гг. Влияние реформы 1892 г. на городскую управу и её социальный состав. Деятельность управы после введения Городового Положения и ее роспуск.

    курсовая работа [134,9 K], добавлен 21.11.2010

  • The history of Russian-American relations and treaties. Rise of the British Colonies against the economic oppression of the British as the start of diplomatic relations between Russia and the USA. The collapse of the USSR and the end of the Cold War.

    контрольная работа [14,1 K], добавлен 07.05.2011

  • Методы археологии библейских стран. Телль и руины, региональные исследования. Регистрация и публикация обнаруженных фактов. Период развития археологии библейских стран в 1890-1892 гг. и с 1946 года по настоящее время. Школы зарубежной археологии.

    контрольная работа [51,9 K], добавлен 18.06.2014

  • The Spanish Empire as one of the largest empires in world history and the first of global extent. Seaborne trade. Broken Spain and England's relations. The main reasons of war. Some main facts about the Spanish Armada. The first colony of England.

    творческая работа [8,9 M], добавлен 13.01.2016

Работы в архивах красиво оформлены согласно требованиям ВУЗов и содержат рисунки, диаграммы, формулы и т.д.
PPT, PPTX и PDF-файлы представлены только в архивах.
Рекомендуем скачать работу.